nep-tre New Economics Papers
on Transport Economics
Issue of 2014‒03‒22
seven papers chosen by
Erik Teodoor Verhoef
VU University Amsterdam

  1. “When supply travels far beyond demand: Causes of oversupply in Spain’s transport infrastructure” By Daniel Albalate; Germà Bel; Xavier Fageda
  2. Are public transport improvements endogenous with respect to employment and income location in a city?. By Carlos Augusto Olarte Bacares
  3. The Impact of Better School Accessibility on Student outcomes By Kenzo Asahi
  4. Criminality spread: a "Boomerang effect" of public transport improvements?. By Carlos Augusto Olarte Bacares
  5. Commuting for meetings By Fosgerau, Mogens; Engelson, Leonid; Franklin, Joel
  6. Long-term mitigation strategies and marginal abatement cost curves : a case study on Brazil By Vogt-Schilb, Adrien; Hallegatte, Stephane; de Gouvello Christophe
  7. The diffusion of electric vehicles: An agent-based microsimulation By McCoy, Daire; Lyons, Sean

  1. By: Daniel Albalate (Faculty of Economics, University of Barcelona); Germà Bel (Faculty of Economics, University of Barcelona); Xavier Fageda (Faculty of Economics, University of Barcelona)
    Abstract: Spain’s transport infrastructure policy has become a paradigmatic case of oversupply and of mismatch with demand. The massive expansion of the country’s transport infrastructure over the last decade has not been a response to demand bottlenecks or previously identified needs. For this reason, the intensity of use today on all interurban modes of transport in Spain falls well below that of other EU countries. This paper analyzes the institutional and regulatory factors that have permitted this policy, allowing us to draw lessons from the Spanish case that should help other countries avoid the pitfalls and shortcomings of Spanish policy. Based on our analysis, we also discuss policy remedies and suggest reforms in different regulatory areas, which could help improve the performance of Spain’s infrastructure policy.
    Keywords: Infrastructure, Transportation, Overcapacity, Regulation, Spain. JEL classification: H54; L91; L98; R41; R42; R48
    Date: 2014–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ira:wpaper:201409&r=tre
  2. By: Carlos Augusto Olarte Bacares (Centre d'Economie de la Sorbonne)
    Abstract: Previous research has proved the existence of a causal relationship between the concentration of jobs in a city and the income of inhabitants. Other researchers have studied the close and nearly causal relationship between those variables and the infrastructure such as highways in different zones of a city. Nevertheless, no one study has taken into account the degree to which each area of a city benefits from the latest improvements to public transport. The aim of this research is to analyse the relationship between the size of the labour market, the income and the employment concentration with respect to improvements to public transport (Transmilenio) in Bogota. The degree of enhancement of public transport in a zone is suspected to be endogenous. Through the use of OLS estimations and then 2SLS, the validation of endogeneity provides sufficient tools to infer causality of improvement of public transport. The size of companies, defined by the number of jobs they offer, plays the role of instrumental variable. In essence, the number of jobs, the size of the labour market and income are largely defined by the level of improvement to urban public transport in each zone of the city but the causality relationship changes depending on the size of companies established in each zone. In the case of Bogota, public transport improvements seams to have a causality relationship with the income of inhabitants in each zone and the number of jobs, and this changes with respect to the size of enterprises. In contrast, the size of the labour market, defined as the number of jobs reachable in a specific time, is not determined by the degree of the presence of public transport enhancement.
    Keywords: Causality, improvements of public transports, endogeneity, effective size of labor market, size of enterprises.
    JEL: J68 R12 R23
    Date: 2014–02
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:mse:cesdoc:14012&r=tre
  3. By: Kenzo Asahi
    Abstract: This paper identifies and quantifies the effects of better transport accessibility on student performance measured by mathematics test scores. A 27 km new subway line and the extension of an existing line in Santiago (Chile) in the mid-2000s reduced the distance between some schools and their nearest subway station. Estimates are derived using fixed effects models that account for endogeneity in the relation between student performance and school-subway network distance. Increased proximity to the subway network is associated with substantially lower test scores.
    Keywords: School accessibility, subway, test scores, student achievement, transport innovations
    JEL: R42 H41 I29
    Date: 2014–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cep:sercdp:0156&r=tre
  4. By: Carlos Augusto Olarte Bacares (Centre d'Economie de la Sorbonne)
    Abstract: The relationship between accessibility or the degree of improvement of urban transport and criminality has been underestimated and close to forgotten. This paper aims to reveal the importance of public transport policies in the evolution of crime configuration in a city. The hypothesis that the probability of transport improvements in a zone depends on some of its socio-economic characteristics is adopted. The use of the propensity score matching technique reveals that the presence of improvements of public transport in a zone of the city has a direct and significant impact on the increase of some types of crime. Likewise, spatial econometrics results expose that crime tends to be contagious in neighbouring zones. The presence of the Transmilenio system in Bogota may share out criminality to other zones of the city. Negative externalities like the better mobility of offenders and, then, their possible choice to expand their criminal activities to new zones, can spoil the positive effects of enhancement of public transport. Far from suggesting no developing public transport or isolating some “dangerous” neighbourhoods or inhabitants, this article shows that improvement of public transport may not only generate positive externalities; policy makers should take into consideration the mutation and shift of criminal behaviours in order to identify possible solutions such as the construction of more establishments providing health, welfare and sporting activities, as is evoked in the results. In this way, the “boomerang effect” of the improvement to transport will be reduced.
    Keywords: Urban public transports improvements, propensity score matching, crime contagion, spatial dependence.
    JEL: C31 K42 R12 R15
    Date: 2014–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:mse:cesdoc:14013&r=tre
  5. By: Fosgerau, Mogens; Engelson, Leonid; Franklin, Joel
    Abstract: Urban congestion causes travel times to exhibit considerable variability, which leads to coordination problems when people have to meet. We analyze a game for the timing of a meeting between two players who must each complete a trip of random duration to reach the meeting, which does not begin until both are present. Players prefer to depart later and also to arrive sooner, provided they do not have to wait for the other player. We find a unique Nash equilibrium, and a continuum of Pareto optima that are strictly better than the Nash equilibrium for both players. Pareto optima may be implemented as Nash equilibria by penalty or compensation schemes.
    Keywords: congestion; random travel time variability; coordination game
    JEL: C7 D1 R4
    Date: 2014
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:54335&r=tre
  6. By: Vogt-Schilb, Adrien; Hallegatte, Stephane; de Gouvello Christophe
    Abstract: Decision makers facing abatement targets need to decide which abatement measures to implement, and in which order. This paper investigates the ability of marginal abatement cost (MAC) curves to inform this decision, reanalysing a MAC curve developed by the World Bank on Brazil. Misinterpreting MAC curves and focusing on short-term targets (e.g., for 2020) would lead to under-invest in expensive, long-to-implement and large-potential options, such as clean transportation infrastructure. Meeting short-term targets with marginal energy-efficiency improvements would lead to carbon-intensive lock-ins that make longer-term targets (e.g., for 2030 and beyond) impossible or too expensive to reach. Improvements to existing MAC curves are proposed, based on (1) enhanced data collection and reporting; (2) a simple optimization tool that accounts for constraints on implementation speeds; and (3) new graphical representations of MAC curves. Designing climate mitigation policies can be done through a pragmatic combination of two approaches. The synergy approach is based on MAC curves to identify the cheapest mitigation options and maximize co-benefits. The urgency approach considers the long-term objective (e.g., halving emissions by 2050) and works backward to identify actions that need to be implemented early, such as public support to clean infrastructure and zero-carbon technologies.
    Keywords: Climate Change Mitigation and Green House Gases,Climate Change Economics,Energy Production and Transportation,Environment and Energy Efficiency,Energy and Environment
    Date: 2014–03–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:wbk:wbrwps:6808&r=tre
  7. By: McCoy, Daire; Lyons, Sean
    Abstract: We implement an agent-based, threshold model of innovation diffusion to simulate the adoption of electric vehicles among Irish households. We use detailed survey microdata to develop a nationally representative, heterogeneous agent population. We then calibrate our agent population to reflect the aggregate socioeconomic characteristics of a number of geographic areas of interest. Our data allow us to create agents with socioeconomic characteristics and environmental preferences. Agents are placed within social networks through which the diffusion process propagates. We find that even if overall adoption is relatively low, mild peer effects could result in large clusters of adopters forming in certain areas. This may put pressure on electricity distribution networks in these areas.
    Keywords: Electric vehicles; Agent-based modelling; Spatial microsimulation
    JEL: C63 D1 O33 R41
    Date: 2014–03–18
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:54560&r=tre

This nep-tre issue is ©2014 by Erik Teodoor Verhoef. It is provided as is without any express or implied warranty. It may be freely redistributed in whole or in part for any purpose. If distributed in part, please include this notice.
General information on the NEP project can be found at http://nep.repec.org. For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese at <director@nep.repec.org>. Put “NEP” in the subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.