nep-rmg New Economics Papers
on Risk Management
Issue of 2015‒03‒05
nineteen papers chosen by
Stan Miles
Thompson Rivers University

  1. A Theory of Liquidity and Risk Management Based on the Inalienability of Risky Human Capital By Patrick Bolton; Neng Wang; Jinqiang Yang
  2. The Cost of Constraints: Risk Management, Agency Theory and Asset Prices By Alankar, Ashwin; Blaustein, Peter; Scholes, Myron S.
  3. Early warning indicators for banking crises: a conditional moments approach By Ferrari, Stijn; Pirovano, Mara
  4. Measures of Systemic Risk By Zachary Feinstein; Birgit Rudloff; Stefan Weber
  5. Options trading in agricultural futures markets: A reasonable instrument of risk hedging, or a driver of agricultural price volatility? By Glauben, Thomas; Prehn, Sören; Dannemann, Tebbe; Brümmer, Bernhard; Loy, Jens-Peter
  6. Leveraging the network: a stress-test framework based on DebtRank By Stefano Battiston; Marco D'Errico; Stefano Gurciullo; Guido Caldarelli
  7. When Is Distress Risk Priced? Evidence from Recessionary Failure Prediction By Ogneva, Maria; Piotroski, Joseph D.; Zakolyukina, Anastasia A.
  8. Active management and mutual fund performance By Meryem Duygun; Juan Carlos Matallín-Sáez; Amparo Soler-Domínguez; Emili Tortosa-Ausina
  9. Tracking banks' systemic importance before and after the crisis By Piergiorgio Alessandri; Sergio Masciantonio; Andrea Zaghini
  10. Modeling and Forecasting Crude Oil Price Volatility: Evidence from Historical and Recent Data By Thomas Lux; Mawuli Segnon; Rangan Gupta
  11. Does Fair Value Accounting Contribute to Procyclical Leverage? By Amel-Zadeh, Amir; Barth, Mary E.; Landsman, Wayne R.
  12. Rational Multi-Curve Models with Counterparty-Risk Valuation Adjustments By Stephane Crepey; Andrea Macrina; Tuyet Mai Nguyen; David Skovmand
  13. Individual Survival Curves Comparing Subjective and Observed Mortality Risk By Luc Bissonnette; Michael Hurd; Pierre-Carl Michaud
  14. Financing as a Supply Chain: The Capital Structure of Banks and Borrowers By Gornall, Will; Strebulaev, Ilya A.
  15. Improving the Effectiveness of Weather-based Insurance: An Application of Copula Approach By Bokusheva, Raushan
  16. Bayesian Estimation of Time-Changed Default Intensity Models By Gordy, Michael B.; Szerszen, Pawel J.
  17. The Variance Risk Premium and Fundamental Uncertainty By Conrad, Christian; Loch, Karin
  18. Comparing systemic risk in European government bonds and national indices By Jan Jurczyk; Alexander Eckrot; Ingo Morgenstern
  19. To sell or to borrow: a theory of bank liquidity management By Kowalik, Michal

  1. By: Patrick Bolton; Neng Wang; Jinqiang Yang
    Abstract: We formulate a dynamic financial contracting problem with risky inalienable human capital. We show that the inalienability of the entrepreneur’s risky human capital not only gives rise to endogenous liquidity limits but also calls for dynamic liquidity and risk management policies via standard securities that firms routinely pursue in practice, such as retained earnings, possible line of credit draw-downs, and hedging via futures and insurance contracts.
    JEL: G3 G32
    Date: 2015–02
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:20979&r=rmg
  2. By: Alankar, Ashwin (Alliance Bernstein); Blaustein, Peter (Oak Hill Advisors); Scholes, Myron S. (Stanford University)
    Abstract: Traditional academic literature has relied on so-called "limits to arbitrage" theories to explain why investment managers are unable to eliminate the effects of investor "irrational" preferences (either the asset-pricing anomalies or the behavioral finance literature) on asset pricing. We demonstrate, however, that investment managers may not eliminate the observed asset-pricing anomalies because they may contribute to their existence. We show that if managers face constraints such as a "tracking-error constraint," coupled with the need to hold liquidity to meet redemptions or to actively-manage investments, they optimally hold higher-volatility securities in their portfolios. Investment constraints, such as tracking-error constraints, however, reduce the principal-agent problems inherent in delegated asset management and serve as effective risk-control tools. Liquidity reserves allow managers to meet redemptions or redeploy risks efficiently. We prove that investment managers will combine a portfolio of active risks (a so-called "alpha portfolio") for a given level of liquidity with a hedging portfolio designed to control tracking error. As the demand for either liquidity or active management increases presumably because of confidence in alpha, the cost of maintaining the tracking-error constraint increases in that the investment managers must finance these demands by selling more lower-volatility securities and holding more higher volatility securities. With more demand for the "alpha" portfolio, managers are forced to buy more of the tracking-error control portfolio. Investment managers and their investors are willing to hold inefficient portfolios and to give up returns, if necessary, to control the tracking-error of their portfolios. Given the liquidity and tracking-error constraints, investment managers concentrate more of their holdings in higher volatility (higher beta) securities. And, we show that it is optimal for investors to limit their manager's use of leverage, which implies that leverage has a different cost other than the cost of borrowing exceeding the return from lending. Empirically, we show that active investment managers, such as mutual funds, hold portfolios that concentrate in higher volatility securities. Moreover, when they change their holdings of their "alpha" portfolios (reduce or increase their tracking error by choice), the relative prices of higher volatility stocks change according to the predictions of the model. That is, if investment managers move closer to a market portfolio, the prices of lower-volatility stocks rise more than the prices of higher-volatility stocks given changes in the prices of other market factors.
    Date: 2014–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ecl:stabus:3086&r=rmg
  3. By: Ferrari, Stijn; Pirovano, Mara
    Abstract: This paper presents a novel methodology to calculate thresholds in an early warning signalling framework for extracting signals useful to predict the occurrence of banking crises. The conditional moments based methodology does not rely on assumptions on an objective function trading off Type I and Type II errors and leads to the identification of zones corresponding to different intensities of the signal. The signalling performance of these signalling zones is similar to that of the traditional early warning method based on the optimisation of a policymaker’s loss function; our methodology in fact outperforms the latter for a number of indicators. The methodology is then extended to allow for country specificities, which leads to a substantial improvement of the signalling power. On average, across all indicators, the country-specific signalling zones outperform the pooled approach, resulting in a larger average true positive rate and a lower false alarms rate.
    Keywords: Early-warning indicators; banking crises; panel data; macro prudential policy
    JEL: C23 E58 G01
    Date: 2015–02
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:62406&r=rmg
  4. By: Zachary Feinstein; Birgit Rudloff; Stefan Weber
    Abstract: Systemic risk refers to the risk that the financial system is susceptible to failures due to the characteristics of the system itself. The tremendous cost of this type of risk requires the design and implementation of tools for the efficient macroprudential regulation of financial institutions. The current paper proposes a novel approach to measuring systemic risk. Key to our construction is a rigorous derivation of systemic risk measures from the structure of the underlying system and the objectives of a financial regulator. The suggested systemic risk measures express systemic risk in terms of capital endowments of the financial firms. Their definition requires two ingredients: first, a cash flow or value model that assigns to the capital allocations of the entities in the system a relevant stochastic outcome. The second ingredient is an acceptability criterion, i.e. a set of random variables that identifies those outcomes that are acceptable from the point of view of a regulatory authority. Systemic risk is measured by the set of allocations of additional capital that lead to acceptable outcomes. The resulting systemic risk measures are set-valued and can be studied using methods from set-valued convex analysis. At the same time, they can easily be applied to the regulation of financial institutions in practice. We explain the conceptual framework and the definition of systemic risk measures, provide an algorithm for their computation, and illustrate their application in numerical case studies. We apply our methodology to systemic risk aggregation as described in Chen, Iyengar & Moallemi (2013) and to network models as suggested in the seminal paper of Eisenberg & Noe (2001), see also Cifuentes, Shin & Ferrucci (2005), Rogers & Veraart (2013), and Awiszus & Weber (2015).
    Date: 2015–02
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:arx:papers:1502.07961&r=rmg
  5. By: Glauben, Thomas; Prehn, Sören; Dannemann, Tebbe; Brümmer, Bernhard; Loy, Jens-Peter
    Abstract: Options trading is increasingly important in more volatile agricultural markets. Options allow for unilateral hedging of price risks, e. g. against falling prices only, and are an indispensable risk management instrument for farmers and grain dealers. Concerns that soaring options trading could spark incremental volatility of international agricultural commodity prices have not been empirically verified to date. Econometric assessments for the MATIF grain maize market suggest that option trading does not have a volatility increasing effect.
    Abstract: Auf volatileren Agrarmärkten gewinnt der Handel mit Optionen zunehmend an Bedeutung. Optionen gestatten die einseitige Absicherung von Preisrisiken, z. B. nur gegen fallende Preise, und stellen ein zunehmend bedeutenderes Instrument für das Risikomanagement von Landwirten und Landhändlern dar. Befürchtungen, dass der zunehmende Handel mit Optionen zu einer erhöhten Volatilität internationaler Agrarrohstoffpreise führen könnte, sind bisher empirisch nicht nachzuweisen. Ökonometrische Schätzungen für den MATIF-Körnermaismarkt weisen darauf hin, dass kein volatilitätserhöhender Effekt durch den Optionshandel festzustellen ist.
    Date: 2014
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:zbw:iamopb:20e&r=rmg
  6. By: Stefano Battiston; Marco D'Errico; Stefano Gurciullo; Guido Caldarelli
    Abstract: We develop a novel stress-test framework to monitor systemic risk in financial systems. The modular structure of the framework allows to accommodate for a variety of shock scenarios, methods to estimate interbank exposures and mechanisms of distress propagation. The main features are as follows. First, the framework allows to estimate and disentangle not only first-round effects (i.e. shock on external assets) and second-round effects (i.e. distress induced in the interbank network), but also third-round effects induced by possible fire sales. Second, it allows to monitor at the same time the impact of shocks on individual or groups of financial institutions as well as their vulnerability to shocks on counterparties or certain asset classes. Third, it includes estimates for loss distributions, thus combining network effects with familiar risk measures such as VaR and CVaR. Fourth, in order to perform robustness analyses and cope with incomplete data, the framework features a module for the generation of sets of networks of interbank exposures that are coherent with the total lending and borrowing of each bank. As an illustration, we carry out a stress-test exercise on a dataset of listed European banks over the years 2008-2013. We find that second-round and third-round effects dominate first-round effects, therefore suggesting that most current stress-test frameworks might lead to a severe underestimation of systemic risk.
    Date: 2015–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:arx:papers:1503.00621&r=rmg
  7. By: Ogneva, Maria (?); Piotroski, Joseph D. (Stanford University); Zakolyukina, Anastasia A. (?)
    Abstract: This paper introduces a new measure of a firm's exposure to systematic distress risk--the probability of a recession at the time of a firm's failure. For stocks in the top quintile of the probability of failure, a median hedge portfolio based on our measure generates a positive risk premium of 5%-8% per annum. Our results differ from the previously documented distress-risk anomaly--a negative correlation between the probability of failure and stock returns. We argue that the probability of failure does not capture systematic distress risk well because it does not differentiate between failures occurring in recessions and expansions.
    Date: 2014–09
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ecl:stabus:3252&r=rmg
  8. By: Meryem Duygun (School of Management, University of Leicester, UK); Juan Carlos Matallín-Sáez (Department of Finance & Accounting, Universitat Jaume I, Castellón, Spain); Amparo Soler-Domínguez (Department of Finance & Accounting, Universitat Jaume I, Castellón, Spain); Emili Tortosa-Ausina (IVIE, Valencia and Department of Economics, Universitat Jaume I, Castellón, Spain)
    Abstract: This paper analyses the relationship between active management and performance in US equity mutual funds over the period 2001-2011 for both gross and net returns. Mutual funds achieve nonzero abnormal performance through strategies that produce differentiated results which are not captured by risk factors. Active management is measured by time-varying parameters, idiosyncratic risk and turnover. The results show a negative aggregate performance close to zero. Performance is worse for non-survivor mutual funds. A U-shaped relation is found between active management and performance, thus both the best and the worst mutual funds show a higher level of active management. This behaviour is also found in the relationship between expenses and performance. Active management therefore implies selecting different strategies or investment bets with higher expenses and an unequal performance is achieved. However some level of persistence in the success of these bets is only fond for the best mutual funds. Moreover the results of these bets show a low level of similarity in terms of herding between the best funds. In contrast, the failures of the worst mutual funds are not persistent before expenses are considered, but there is a higher level of herding among these funds. In sum, the best funds reflect persistence and particular skills, whereas the worst present non-persistence and common failures.
    Keywords: Mutual fund, performance, active management, expenses, persistence, herding
    JEL: G23 G11
    Date: 2015
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:jau:wpaper:2015/01&r=rmg
  9. By: Piergiorgio Alessandri (Bank of Italy); Sergio Masciantonio (Bank of Italy); Andrea Zaghini (Bank of Italy)
    Abstract: We develop a methodology to identify and rank ‘systemically important financial institutions’ (SIFIs). Our approach is consistent with that followed by the Financial Stability Board but, unlike the latter, it is free of judgment and it is based entirely on publicly available data, thus filling the gap between the official views of the regulator and those that market participants form with their own information set. We apply the methodology on three samples of banks (global, EU and euro area) for the years 2007-12.
    Keywords: systemic risk, too big to fail
    JEL: G21 G01 G18
    Date: 2015–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:bdi:opques:qef_259_15&r=rmg
  10. By: Thomas Lux (Department of Economics, University of Kiel, Kiel, Germany); Mawuli Segnon (Department of Economics, University of Kiel, Germany); Rangan Gupta (Department of Economics, University of Pretoria)
    Abstract: This paper uses the Markov-switching multifractal (MSM) model and generalized autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity (GARCH)-type models to forecast oil price volatility over the time periods from January 02, 1875 to December 31, 1895 and from January 03, 1977 to March 24, 2014. Based on six dierent loss functions and by means of the superior predictive ability (SPA) test, we evaluate and compare their forecasting performance at short and long horizons. The empirical results indicate that none of our volatility models can uniformly outperform other models across all six different loss functions. However, the new MSM model comes out as the model that most often across forecasting horizons and subsamples cannot be outperformed by other models, with long memory GARCH-type models coming out second best.
    Keywords: Crude oil prices, GARCH, Multifractal processes, SPA test
    JEL: C52 C53 C22
    Date: 2015–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pre:wpaper:201511&r=rmg
  11. By: Amel-Zadeh, Amir (?); Barth, Mary E. (Stanford University); Landsman, Wayne R. (?)
    Abstract: We describe analytically commercial bank behavior focusing on actions banks take in response to economic gains and losses on their assets to meet regulatory leverage requirements. Our analysis shows that absent differences in regulatory risk weights across assets, leverage cannot be procyclical. We test the analytical description's predictions using a sample of US commercial banks, during economic upturns and downturns, including the recent financial crisis. Although we find a significantly positive relation between change in leverage and change in assets, this procyclical relation evaporates when change in each bank's weighted average regulatory risk weight is included in the estimating equation. We also find that all changes in equity, including those arising from fair value accounting, are significantly negatively related to change in leverage, which is inconsistent with fair value accounting contributing to procyclical leverage. In addition, we find no evidence of a relation between change in leverage and the interaction between change in assets arising from fair value accounting and other changes in assets. Taken together, the empirical evidence indicates that fair value accounting is not a source of procyclical leverage. The key conclusion we draw is that bank regulatory requirements, particularly regulatory leverage determined using regulatory risk-weighted assets, explain why banks' leverage can be procyclical, and that fair value accounting does not.
    Date: 2014–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ecl:stabus:3073&r=rmg
  12. By: Stephane Crepey; Andrea Macrina; Tuyet Mai Nguyen; David Skovmand
    Abstract: We develop a multi-curve term structure setup in which the modelling ingredients are expressed by rational functionals of Markov processes. We calibrate to LIBOR swaptions data and show that a rational two-factor lognormal multi-curve model is sufficient to match market data with accuracy. We elucidate the relationship between the models developed and calibrated under a risk-neutral measure Q and their consistent equivalence class under the real-world probability measure P. The consistent P-pricing models are applied to compute the risk exposures which may be required to comply with regulatory obligations. In order to compute counterparty-risk valuation adjustments, such as CVA, we show how positive default intensity processes with rational form can be derived. We flesh out our study by applying the results to a basis swap contract.
    Date: 2015–02
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:arx:papers:1502.07397&r=rmg
  13. By: Luc Bissonnette; Michael Hurd; Pierre-Carl Michaud
    Abstract: In this paper, we compare individual survival curves constructed from objective (actual mortality) and elicited subjective information (probability of survival to a given target age). We develop a methodology to estimate jointly subjective and objective individualsurvival curves accounting for rounding on subjective reports of perceived mortality risk. We make use of the long follow-up period in the Health and Retirement Study and the high quality of mortality data to estimate individual survival curves which feature both observed and unobserved heterogeneity. This allows us to compare objective and subjective estimates of remaining life expectancy for various groups, evaluate subjective expectations of joint survival and widowhood by household, and compare objective and subjective mortality with standard life-cycle models of consumption.
    Keywords: Subjective probabilities, old age mortality, joint survival of couples,
    JEL: C81 D84 I10
    Date: 2015–02–25
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cir:cirwor:2015s-08&r=rmg
  14. By: Gornall, Will (Stanford University); Strebulaev, Ilya A. (Stanford University)
    Abstract: We develop a model of the joint capital structure decisions of banks and their borrowers. Strikingly high bank leverage emerges naturally from the interplay between two sets of forces. First, seniority and diversification reduce bank asset volatility by an order of magnitude relative to that of their borrowers. Second, previously unstudied supply chain effects mean that highly levered financial intermediaries can offer the lowest interest rates. Low asset volatility enables banks to take on high leverage safely; supply chain effects compel them to do so. Firms with low leverage also arise naturally, as borrowers internalize the systematic risk costs they impose on their lenders. Because risk assessment techniques from the Basel framework underlie our model, we can quantify the impact capital regulation and other government interventions have on leverage and fragility. Deposit insurance and the expectation of government bailouts increase not only bank risk taking, but also borrower risk taking. Capital regulation lowers bank leverage but can lead to compensating increases in the leverage of borrowers, which can paradoxically lead to riskier banks. Doubling current capital requirements would reduce the default risk of banks exposed to high moral hazard by up to 90%, with only a small increase in bank interest rates.
    Date: 2014–04
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ecl:stabus:3102&r=rmg
  15. By: Bokusheva, Raushan
    Abstract: The study develops the methodology for a copula-based weather index insurance rating. As the copula approach is better suited for modeling tail dependence than the standard linear correlation method, we suppose that copulas are more adequate for pricing a weather index insurance contract against extreme weather events. To capture the dependence structure in the left tail of the joint distribution of a weather variable and the farm yield, we employ the Gumbel survival copula. Our results indicate that, given the choice of an appropriate weather index to signal extreme drought occurrence, a copula-based weather insurance contact might provide higher risk reduction compared to a regression-based indemnification.
    Keywords: catastrophic insurance, weather index insurance, copula, insurance contract design
    JEL: C18 G22 Q14
    Date: 2014–01–22
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:62339&r=rmg
  16. By: Gordy, Michael B. (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (U.S.)); Szerszen, Pawel J. (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (U.S.))
    Abstract: We estimate a reduced-form model of credit risk that incorporates stochastic volatility in default intensity via stochastic time-change. Our Bayesian MCMC estimation method overcomes nonlinearity in the measurement equation and state-dependent volatility in the state equation. We implement on firm-level time-series of CDS spreads, and find strong in-sample evidence of stochastic volatility in this market. Relative to the widely-used CIR model for the default intensity, we find that stochastic time-change offers modest benefit in fitting the cross-section of CDS spreads at each point in time, but very large improvements in fitting the time-series, i.e., in bringing agreement between the moments of the default intensity and the model-implied moments. Finally, we obtain model-implied out-of-sample density forecasts via auxiliary particle filter, and find that the time-changed model strongly outperforms the baseline CIR model.
    Keywords: Bayesian estimation; CDS; CIR process; credit derivatives; MCMC; particle filter; stochastic time change
    JEL: C11 C15 C58 G12 G17
    Date: 2015–01–06
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:fip:fedgfe:2015-02&r=rmg
  17. By: Conrad, Christian; Loch, Karin
    Abstract: We propose a new measure of the expected variance risk premium that is based on a forecast of the conditional variance from a GARCH-MIDAS model. We find that the new measure has strong predictive ability for future U.S. aggregate stock market returns and rationalize this result by showing that the new measure effectively isolates fundamental uncertainty as the factor that drives the variance risk premium.
    Keywords: Variance risk premium; return predictability; VIX; GARCH-MIDAS; economic uncertainty; vol-of-vol
    Date: 2015–02–27
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:awi:wpaper:0583&r=rmg
  18. By: Jan Jurczyk; Alexander Eckrot; Ingo Morgenstern
    Abstract: It has been shown, that the systemic risk contained in financial markets can be indicated by the change of cross-correlation between different indices and stocks. This change is tracked by using principle component analysis (PCA). We use this technique to investigate the systemic risk contained in European economy by comparing government long term bonds and indices.
    Date: 2015–02
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:arx:papers:1502.07367&r=rmg
  19. By: Kowalik, Michal
    Keywords: Banking; Liquidity; Interbank markets; Secondary markets
    JEL: G21 G28
    Date: 2014–12–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:fip:fedkrw:rwp14-18&r=rmg

This nep-rmg issue is ©2015 by Stan Miles. It is provided as is without any express or implied warranty. It may be freely redistributed in whole or in part for any purpose. If distributed in part, please include this notice.
General information on the NEP project can be found at http://nep.repec.org. For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese at <director@nep.repec.org>. Put “NEP” in the subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.