|
on Regulation |
Issue of 2007‒01‒02
thirteen papers chosen by Christian Calmes Universite du Quebec en Outaouais, Canada |
By: | Diana Hancock; Andreas Lehnert; Wayne Passmore; Shane M. Sherlund |
Abstract: | Basel II bank capital regulations are designed to be substantially more risk sensitive than the current regulations. In the United States, only the largest banks would be required to adopt Basel II; other depositories could choose to adopt such standards or to remain under the Basel I capital standards. We consider possible effects of this two-pronged or "bifurcated" approach on the market for residential mortgages. Specifically, we analyze whether those institutions that adopt Basel II will enjoy lower costs than nonadopters and whether they have an incentive to retain mortgages in their own portfolios. We find that (1) despite the large differences in regulatory capital requirements between adopters and nonadopters, it is unlikely that there will be any measurable effect of Basel II implementation on most mortgage rates and, consequently, any direct impact on the competition between adopters and nonadopters for originating or holding residential mortgages; (2) the most significant competitive impact may be felt among mortgage securitizers; and (3) adopters might have increased profits from some mortgages relative to nonadopters because they will capture some of the deadweight losses that occur under the current regulatory regime, but nonadopters would likely retain their market shares. |
Date: | 2006 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:fip:fedgfe:2006-46&r=reg |
By: | Eijffinger, Sylvester C W; Rossi, Alberto |
Abstract: | The paper focuses on labor and product market deregulations, as fundamental elements in the passage from an investment to an innovation-based economy. The approach undertaken is prominently empirical. After a very brief description of the regulatory levels on the two sides of the Atlantic, we take two cornerstone theoretical models: one developed by Robert Gordon (1997), the other developed by Blanchard and Giavazzi (2003) and we observe how well their theoretical predictions are supported by hard data. We conclude with an independent study on the accuracy of the IMD competitiveness index in predicting the overall economic performance of countries close to the technological frontier. |
Keywords: | employment; growth; IMD competitiveness index; productivity; regulation; unemployment; wages |
JEL: | D24 E24 J50 L16 |
Date: | 2006–12 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cpr:ceprdp:5988&r=reg |
By: | Auriol, Emmanuelle; Picard, Pierre M |
Abstract: | The paper analyses governments’ trade-off between fiscal benefits and consumer surplus in privatization reforms of noncompetitive industries in developing countries. Under privatization, the control rights are transferred to private interests so that public subsidies decline. This benefit for tax-payers comes at the cost of price increases for consumers. In developing countries, tight budget constraints imply that privatization may be optimal for low profitability segments. For highly profitable public utilities, the combination of allocative inefficiency and critical budgetary conditions may favour public ownership. Finally, once a market segment gives room for more than one firm, governments prefer to regulate the industry. In the absence of a credible regulatory agency, regulation is achieved through public ownership. |
Keywords: | developing countries; government budget constraint; infrastructure; privatization; public utilities; regulation |
JEL: | H54 L33 L43 |
Date: | 2006–12 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cpr:ceprdp:6018&r=reg |
By: | Almeida, Rita; Carneiro, Pedro |
Abstract: | This paper investigates how enforcement of labour regulation affects the firm's use of informal labour, firm size and firm performance. Using firm level data on employment, capita, and output, census data on informal employment at the city level, and administrative data on enforcement of regulation at the city level, we show that in areas where law enforcement is stricter firms employ a smaller proportion of informal workers. Furthermore, by reducing the firm's access to unregulated labour stricter enforcement is also associated with smaller firms, less fluid labour markets, and (possibly) lower labour productivity. We control for different regional and firm characteristics, and we instrument enforcement with the distance between firm location and the location of an enforcement office, a measure of access of labour inspectors to firms. Taken together, our findings suggest that increased access to labour flexibility frees the firm from growth constraints, and it is likely to contribute to an improvement in productivity. |
Keywords: | employment; informal sector; labour demand; labour markets; productivity; regulation |
JEL: | H00 H10 J50 K20 L50 L60 O17 O40 |
Date: | 2006–12 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cpr:ceprdp:5976&r=reg |
By: | Ciccone, Antonio; Papaioannou, Elias |
Abstract: | Does cutting red tape foster entrepreneurship in industries with the potential to expand? We address this question by combining the time needed to comply with government entry procedures in 45 countries with industry-level data on employment growth and growth in the number of establishments during the 1980s. Our main empirical finding is that countries where it takes less time to register new businesses have seen more entry in industries that experienced expansionary global demand and technology shifts. Our estimates take into account that proxying global industry shifts using data from only one country--or group of countries with similar entry regulations--will in general yield biased results. |
Keywords: | entry; entry regulation; globally expanding industries |
JEL: | E6 F43 L16 |
Date: | 2006–12 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cpr:ceprdp:5996&r=reg |
By: | Bernhard Ebbinghaus (MZES, University of Mannheim); Werner Eichhorst (IZA Bonn) |
Abstract: | The paper provides an overview of institutional provisions and reforms regarding employment protection, active and passive labor market policies in Germany as well as of actors' responsibilities in these areas. It covers the period between the early 1990s and the most recent Hartz reforms. Empirical data on labor market outcomes with respect to the levels and structures of both employment and unemployment complements this study. |
Keywords: | employment protection, active labor market policy, unemployment insurance, Germany |
JEL: | J60 J68 |
Date: | 2006–12 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp2505&r=reg |
By: | Luca Anderlini; Leonardo Felli; Andrew Postlewaite |
Abstract: | We describe and analyze a contractual environment that allows a role for an active court. The model we analyze is the same as in Anderlini, Felli, and Postlewaite (2006). An active court can improve on the outcome that the parties would achieve without it. The institutional role of the court is to maximize the parties’ welfare under a veil of ignorance. In Anderlini, Felli, and Postlewaite (2006) the possibility of “menu contracts” between the informed buyer and the uninformed seller is described but not analyzed. Here, we fully analyze this case. We find that if we maintain the assumption that one of the potential objects of trade is not contractible ex-ante, the results of Anderlini, Felli, and Postlewaite (2006) survive intact. If however we let all “widgets” be contractible ex-ante, then multiple equilibria obtain. In this case the role for an active court is to ensure the inefficient pooling equilibria do not exist alongside the superior ones in which separation occurs. |
Keywords: | optimal courts, informational externalities, ex-ante welfare, informed principal, menu contracts |
JEL: | C79 D74 D89 K40 L14 |
Date: | 2006 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ces:ceswps:_1852&r=reg |
By: | Mahima Puri (Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations); Anjali Varma (Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations) |
Date: | 2005–07 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ind:icrier:166&r=reg |
By: | Subhayu Bandyopadhyay; Howard J. Wall |
Abstract: | This paper presents a model of legal migration from one source country to two host countries, both of which can control their levels of immigration. Because of complementarities between capital and labor, the return on capital is positively related to the level of immigration. Consequently, when capital is immobile, host nations’ optimal levels of immigration are positively related to their capital endowments. Further, when capital is mobile between the two host nations, the common return on capital is a function of the levels of immigration in both countries, meaning that immigration is a public good. As a result, when immigration imposes costs on host countries, the Nash equilibrium results in free riding and less immigration than would occur in the cooperative equilibrium. These results are qualitatively unaltered when capital mobility extends to the source nation. |
Date: | 2006 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:fip:fedlwp:2006-062&r=reg |
By: | Arpita Mukherjee (Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations); Paramita Deb Gupta (Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations) |
Abstract: | ITES/BPO services is an important and growing component of India's trade in services with the US. While the Indian government has implemented several measures to support the growth of this sector, Indian companies face various barriers in the US market such as anti-outsourcing regulations, restrictive visa/work permit regime and concerns relating to protection of sensitive data. Multilateral negotiations would have been the best route to address many of these barriers, but with the recent suspension of the Doha Round of talks, it has become important for countries to evaluate alternative routes such as bilateral Free Trade Agreements. In fact, after the suspension of the multilateral negotiations, both India and the US have refocused on bilateral agreements. In this context, this study discusses the current and potential trade between India and the US in ITES/BPO services, identifies barriers to trade and explores how an FTA can enhance bilateral trade in this sector. The study shows that the US-FTAs have achieved a higher level of liberalization than in the WTO. It suggests various negotiating strategies for India such as a negative list approach, signing mutual recognition agreements in key professional services, asking for a H1B1 type of visa, pushing for removal of domestic regulation-related barriers, among others which would enhance market access for Indian companies in the US. It also points out that Indo-US collaborations for data protection, skill development and raising awareness of the advantages of outsourcing in the US would be mutually beneficial. The study discusses regulatory and other reforms which will improve the productivity, efficiency and global competitiveness of this sector and enable the country to gain from the FTA. |
Keywords: | Indo-US FTA, GATS, Bilateral Agreements, business process outsourcing, IT-enabled services. |
JEL: | F13 F14 L86 |
Date: | 2006–09 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ind:icrier:187&r=reg |
By: | John A. List; Michael Margolis; Daniel E. Osgood |
Abstract: | We develop theory and present a suite of theoretically consistent empirical measures to explore the extent to which market intervention inadvertently alters resource allocation in a sequentialmove principal/agent game. We showcase our approach empirically by exploring the extent to which the U.S. Endangered Species Act has altered land development patterns. We report evidence indicating significant acceleration of development directly after each of several events deemed likely to raise fears among owners of habitat land. Our preferred estimate suggests an overall acceleration of land development by roughly one year. We also find from complementary hedonic regression models that habitat parcels declined in value when the habitat map was published, which is consistent with our estimates of the degree of preemption. These results have clear implications for policymakers, who continue to discuss alternative regulatory frameworks for species preservation. More generally, our modeling strategies can be widely applied -- from any particular economic environment that has a sequential-move nature to the narrower case of the political economy of regulation. |
JEL: | H23 H41 |
Date: | 2006–12 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:12777&r=reg |
By: | Samir R. Gandhi (Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations) |
Date: | 2006–06 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ind:icrier:181&r=reg |
By: | A. Mitchell Polinsky; Steven Shavell |
Abstract: | We analyze a model in which firms are able to acquire information about product risks and may or may not be required to disclose this information. We initially study the effect of disclosure rules assuming that firms are not liable for the harm caused by their products. Although mandatory disclosure obviously is superior to voluntary disclosure given the information about product risks that firms possess -- since such information has value to consumers -- voluntary disclosure induces firms to acquire more information about product risks because they can keep silent if the information is unfavorable. The latter effect could lead to higher social welfare under voluntary disclosure. The same results hold if firms are liable for harm under the negligence standard of liability. Under strict liability, however, firms are indifferent about revealing information concerning product risk, and mandatory and voluntary disclosure rules are equivalent. |
JEL: | D18 D62 D82 H23 K13 L15 |
Date: | 2006–12 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:12776&r=reg |