nep-pub New Economics Papers
on Public Finance
Issue of 2024‒08‒26
ten papers chosen by
Kwang Soo Cheong, Johns Hopkins University


  1. Optimal Taxation in the Automated Era By Nakatani, Ryota
  2. Taxing Capital in a Globalized World: The Effects of Automatic Information Exchange By Hjalte Fejerskov Boas; Niels Johannesen; Claus Thustrup Kreiner; Lauge Truels Larsen; Gabriel Zucman
  3. Billionaire Superstar: Public Image and Demand for Taxation By Ricardo Perez-Truglia; Jeffrey Yusof
  4. Tax Incentives for Charitable Giving: New Findings from the TCJA By Xiao Han; Daniel M. Hungerman; Mark Ottoni-Wilhelm
  5. Lessons from the Biggest Business Tax Cut in US History By Gabriel Chodorow-Reich; Owen M. Zidar; Eric Zwick
  6. Property Taxes and Housing Allocation under Financial Constraints By Joshua Coven; Sebastian Golder; Arpit Gupta; Abdoulaye Ndiaye
  7. Information Provision and Support for Inheritance Taxation: Evidence from a Representative Survey Experiment in Germany By Luna Bellani; Kattalina Berriochoa; Mark Kapteina; Guido Schwerdt
  8. The Distributional Effects of U.S. Tax Credits for Heat Pumps, Solar Panels, and Electric Vehicles By Severin Borenstein; Lucas W. Davis
  9. The Impact of Incarceration on Employment, Earnings, and Tax Filing By Andrew Garin; Dmitri K. Koustas; Carl McPherson; Samuel Norris; Matthew Pecenco; Evan K. Rose; Yotam Shem-Tov; Jeffrey Weaver
  10. The Effects of the 2021 Child Tax Credit on Parents’ Psychological Well-Being By Lisa A. Gennetian; Anna Gassman-Pines

  1. By: Nakatani, Ryota
    Abstract: Using the consumption equivalent welfare gain as social welfare and assuming an automation technology shock, we derive the optimal tax rates for various tax policy instruments in the steady state of the model economy calibrated for the U.S. We find that the optimal capital income tax rate lies between 22 percent and 23 percent under realistic technology shocks, while the tax rate could be higher if the elasticity of substitution between automation-related capital and unskilled workers becomes greater. Another finding is that the optimal labor income tax rate for unskilled workers is lower than that for skilled workers, although the social welfare gain from such optimal labor income tax reform is very small. We also find that the optimal tax rate on automation-related capital is zero due to its large economic distortion in the long run. Furthermore, the redistributive mechanism of the optimal consumption tax depends on the elasticity of substitution between automation-related capital and unskilled workers. Finally, we find that Pareto-efficient optimal tax reform is a combination of raising the capital income tax rate and lowering the consumption tax rate from the status quo. When automation-augmented technological progress is rapid, it is even optimal to rely solely on the capital income tax rate hike as a redistributive tax policy tool.
    Keywords: Automation; Optimal Taxation; Capital Income Tax; Labor Income Tax; Consumption Tax; Robot Tax; Tax Mix
    JEL: C68 E25 H21 H24 H25 H30 O30 O40
    Date: 2024–06–29
    URL: https://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:121347
  2. By: Hjalte Fejerskov Boas; Niels Johannesen; Claus Thustrup Kreiner; Lauge Truels Larsen; Gabriel Zucman
    Abstract: In the second half of the 2010s more than 100 countries—including all large offshore financial centers—started to automatically exchange bank information with foreign tax authorities. This informational big-bang marks a break with the situation of offshore bank secrecy that prevailed before. We study its effects on tax compliance by analyzing the universe of information reports sent by foreign banks to Danish authorities, matched to population-wide micro-data on income, wealth, and cross-border bank transfers. In response to the automatic exchange of bank information, tax evaders may repatriate previously undeclared offshore wealth, they may start to self-report offshore income to the tax authorities, or the tax authorities may detect their evasion in audits that use the new information reports. Using a variety of research designs, we find large compliance effects along all these margins, with the largest response coming from repatriation of wealth. Overall we estimate that the automatic exchange of bank information has closed about 70% of the offshore tax gap. These results highlight the power of international cooperation to improve tax compliance: tax evasion is not a law of nature in a globalized world.
    JEL: D31 H24 H26 K34
    Date: 2024–07
    URL: https://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:32714
  3. By: Ricardo Perez-Truglia; Jeffrey Yusof
    Abstract: In the United States, there are 741 billionaires with a combined net worth of $5.2 trillion. These billionaires live highly public lives, with some achieving superstar status. Despite growing inequality, billionaires face effective tax rates lower than the average American. Is this due to a lack of public support for taxation? Is it due to misperceptions about billionaires’ lives and careers? To address these questions, we conducted a survey experiment with a sample of 9, 013 Americans. We designed multiple treatments based on research on preferences for redistribution and arguments made by academics, journalists, and the general public to increase taxes on the ultra-wealthy. Our findings reveal significant misperceptions about billionaires, with individuals updating their beliefs in response to information. Contrary to expert predictions that all treatments would positively affect the demand for taxation, most treatments have a null or negative effect. Providing information about the lavish lifestyles of billionaires does have a robust positive effect on the demand for taxation.
    JEL: D31 H24
    Date: 2024–07
    URL: https://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:32712
  4. By: Xiao Han; Daniel M. Hungerman; Mark Ottoni-Wilhelm
    Abstract: The Tax Cuts and Jobs Act eliminated federal charitable giving incentives for roughly 20 percent of US income-tax payers. We study the impact of this on giving. Basic theory and our empirical results suggest heterogeneous effects for taxpayers with different amounts of itemizable expenses. Overall, the reform decreased charitable giving by about $20 billion annually. Using a new method to adjust estimates for retimed giving, we find evidence of moderate intertemporal shifts from pre-announcement of the law. The permanent price elasticity of giving estimates range from .6 for the average donor to over 2 for those predicted to be most responsive to the reform.
    JEL: D64 H41 L31
    Date: 2024–07
    URL: https://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:32737
  5. By: Gabriel Chodorow-Reich; Owen M. Zidar; Eric Zwick
    Abstract: We assess the business provisions of the 2017 Tax Cuts and Jobs Act, the biggest corporate tax cut in US history. We draw five lessons. First, corporate tax revenue fell by 40 percent due to the lower rate and more generous expensing. Second, firms with larger declines in their effective tax wedge increased investment relatively more. In aggregate, we suggest a loose consensus from the literature that total tangible corporate investment increased by 11 percent. Third, the business tax provisions increased economic growth and wages by less than advertised by the Act’s proponents, with long-run GDP higher by less than 1% and labor income by less than $1, 000 per employee. Fourth, provisions that increase foreign investment by US-based multinationals also boost their domestic operations. Fifth, some of the expired and expiring provisions, such as accelerated depreciation, generate more investment per dollar of tax revenue than others.
    JEL: H25 H32 K34
    Date: 2024–07
    URL: https://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:32672
  6. By: Joshua Coven; Sebastian Golder; Arpit Gupta; Abdoulaye Ndiaye
    Abstract: Property taxes impact the housing distribution across generations. Low property taxes lead to concentrated ownership among elderly empty-nesters, limiting housing for financially constrained young families. Conversely, high property taxes act as a “forced mortgage, ” reducing upfront downpayments and enabling greater homeownership among younger households. We show in an overlapping generations model that raising property taxes in low-tax California to match those in higher-tax Texas increases homeownership in California by 4.6% and among younger households by 7.4% in steady state. Asset taxes can reallocate housing to higher-valuation households in the presence of financial constraints, providing an independent rationale for property taxes.
    Keywords: property taxes, housing affordability, housing inequality
    JEL: H71 R21 H24 J11
    Date: 2024
    URL: https://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ces:ceswps:_11203
  7. By: Luna Bellani; Kattalina Berriochoa; Mark Kapteina; Guido Schwerdt
    Abstract: We study the effects of information on attitudes towards inheritance taxation using survey experiments fielded in Germany. We show that information about tax allowances increases demand for higher taxes and shifts public opinion from favoring abolition to supporting the tax. Effects are primarily due to a prevalent underestimation of tax allowances and the alteration of people’s expectations of being affected by such taxes. In contrast, information highlighting the increasing proportion of inherited wealth only negligibly affects policy demand. Our results suggest that pocketbook motives and misinformation may contribute to explaining the paradox of limited demand for inheritance taxation despite growing inequality concerns.
    Keywords: capital taxation, equality of opportunity, inheritance tax, information, randomized experiment
    JEL: H20 D72 D83
    Date: 2024
    URL: https://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ces:ceswps:_11189
  8. By: Severin Borenstein; Lucas W. Davis
    Abstract: Over the last two decades, U.S. households have received $47 billion in tax credits for buying heat pumps, solar panels, electric vehicles, and other “clean energy” technologies. Using information from tax returns, we show that these tax credits have gone predominantly to higher-income households. The bottom three income quintiles have received about 10% of all credits, while the top quintile has received about 60%. The most extreme is the tax credit for electric vehicles, for which the top quintile has received more than 80% of all credits. The concentration of tax credits among high-income filers is relatively constant over time, though we do find a slight broadening for the electric vehicle credit since 2018. The paper then turns to the related question of cost effectiveness, examining how clean energy technology adoption has changed over time and discussing some of the broader economic considerations for this type of tax credit.
    JEL: H23 Q42 Q58
    Date: 2024–07
    URL: https://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:32688
  9. By: Andrew Garin; Dmitri K. Koustas; Carl McPherson; Samuel Norris; Matthew Pecenco; Evan K. Rose; Yotam Shem-Tov; Jeffrey Weaver
    Abstract: We study the effect of incarceration on wages, self-employment, and taxes and transfers in North Carolina and Ohio using two quasi-experimental research designs: discontinuities in sentencing guidelines and random assignment to judges. Across both states, incarceration generates short-term drops in economic activity while individuals remain in prison. As a result, a year-long sentence decreases cumulative earnings over five years by 13%. Beyond five years, however, there is no evidence of lower employment, wage earnings, or self-employment in either state, as well as among defendants with no prior incarceration history. These results suggest that upstream factors, such as other types of criminal justice interactions or pre-existing labor market detachment, are more likely to be the cause of low earnings among the previously incarcerated, who we estimate would earn just $5, 000 per year on average if spared a prison sentence.
    JEL: H2 J01 J20
    Date: 2024–07
    URL: https://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:32747
  10. By: Lisa A. Gennetian; Anna Gassman-Pines
    Abstract: Although improving psychological well-being was not the explicit focus of the 2021 expanded Child Tax Credit (CTC), psychological health outcomes may have been affected by the positive income shocks generated by the credit. In this chapter we ask: How did the 2021 expanded CTC affect parents’ psychological well-being? Some studies have found that the CTC led to reductions in parental reports of clinical levels of depression and anxiety and in subclinical depressive and anxiety symptoms. Using similar methods, other studies have found no effect on these same outcomes. Importantly, however, the evidence does not point to the CTC worsening psychological well-being. We conclude that the evidence so far is thin, narrow, and mixed, even when our review is expanded to comparable studies on the impact of income support. Alignment of policy objectives with a broader range of measurement approaches will be important in building a more conclusive evidence base.
    JEL: H31 I3 J18
    Date: 2024–07
    URL: https://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:32662

This nep-pub issue is ©2024 by Kwang Soo Cheong. It is provided as is without any express or implied warranty. It may be freely redistributed in whole or in part for any purpose. If distributed in part, please include this notice.
General information on the NEP project can be found at https://nep.repec.org. For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese at <director@nep.repec.org>. Put “NEP” in the subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.