nep-opm New Economics Papers
on Open MacroEconomics
Issue of 2008‒12‒14
sixteen papers chosen by
Martin Berka
Massey University

  1. Does Openness to International Financial Flows Raise Productivity Growth? By M. Ayhan Kose; Eswar S. Prasad; Marco E. Terrones
  2. Interactions between monetary policy and exchange rate in inflation targeting emerging countries: the case of three East Asian countries By Sek, Siok Kun
  3. Assessing the Emerging Global Financial Architecture: Measuring the Trilemma's Configurations over Time By Joshua Aizenman; Menzie D. Chinn; Hiro Ito
  4. Re-Evaluating Swedish Membership in EMU: Evidence from an Estimated Model By Ulf Söderström
  5. Financial Development, Technological Change in Emerging Countries and Global Imbalances By Kenza Benhima
  6. A Reappraisal of the Allocation Puzzle through the Portfolio Approach By Kenza Benhima
  7. Nonlinear Exchange Rate Predictability By Carlos Felipe Lopez Suarez; Jose Antonio Rodriguez Lopez
  8. Business Cycle in the euro Area By Domenico Giannone; Michele Lenza; Lucrezia Reichlin
  9. The Estimated Effects of the Euro on Trade: Why Are They Below Historical Effects of Monetary Unions Among Smaller Countries? By Jeffrey A. Frankel
  10. Business Cycles in the Euro Area By Domenico Giannone; Michele Lenza; Lucrezia Reichlin
  11. Financial Crash, Commodity Prices and Global Imbalances By Ricardo J. Caballero; Emmanuel Farhi; Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas
  12. A Nonparametric Approach to Evaluating Inflation-Targeting Regimes By Weshah Razzak; Rabie Nasser
  13. Sovereign Wealth Funds: Stylized Facts about their Determinants and Governance By Joshua Aizenman; Reuven Glick
  14. Credit Constraints, Heterogeneous Firms, and International Trade By Kalina Manova
  15. Inflation Targeting and Real Exchange Rates in Emerging Markets By Joshua Aizenman; Michael Hutchison; Ilan Noy
  16. The Cross-Section of Output and Inflation in a Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model with Sticky Prices By Döpke, J.; Funke, M.; Holly, S.; Weber, S.

  1. By: M. Ayhan Kose; Eswar S. Prasad; Marco E. Terrones
    Abstract: Economic theory has identified a number of channels through which openness to international financial flows could raise productivity growth. However, while there is a vast empirical literature analyzing the impact of financial openness on output growth, far less attention has been paid to its effects on productivity growth. We provide a comprehensive analysis of the relationship between financial openness and total factor productivity (TFP) growth using an extensive dataset that includes various measures of productivity and financial openness for a large sample of countries. We find that de jure capital account openness has a robust positive effect on TFP growth. The effect of de facto financial integration on TFP growth is less clear, but this masks an important and novel result. We find strong evidence that FDI and portfolio equity liabilities boost TFP growth while external debt is actually negatively correlated with TFP growth. The negative relationship between external debt liabilities and TFP growth is attenuated in economies with higher levels of financial development and better institutions.
    JEL: F36 F41 F43
    Date: 2008–12
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:14558&r=opm
  2. By: Sek, Siok Kun
    Abstract: This paper investigates empirically how the reaction of monetary policy to exchange rate has changed after the adoption of inflation targeting regime in three East Asian countries. Using a structural VAR and single equation methods, this study shows that the reactions of monetary policy to exchange rate shocks as well as CPI (demand shocks) and output (supply shocks) have declined under the inflation targeting environment. The policy function reacts weakly to the exchange rate movements before and after the financial crisis of 1997 in two out of the three countries.
    Keywords: exchange rate; inflation targeting; policy reaction function
    JEL: E58 E52 F41
    Date: 2008
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:12034&r=opm
  3. By: Joshua Aizenman; Menzie D. Chinn; Hiro Ito
    Abstract: We develop a methodology that allows us to characterize in an intuitive manner the choices countries have made with respect to the trilemma during the post Bretton-Woods period. The first part of the paper deals with positive aspects of the trilemma, outlining new metrics for measuring the degree of exchange rate flexibility, monetary independence, and capital account openness. The evolution of our "trilemma indexes" illustrates that after the early 1990s, industrialized countries accelerated financial openness, but reduced the extent of monetary independence while sharply increasing exchange rate stability. This process culminated at the end of the 1990s with the introduction of the euro. In contrast, the group of developing countries pursued exchange rate stability as their key priority up to 1990, although many countries moved toward greater exchange rate flexibility from the early 1970s onward. Since 2000, measures of the three trilemma variables have converged towards intermediate levels characterizing managed flexibility, using sizable international reserves as a buffer, thus retaining some degree of monetary autonomy. Using these indexes, we also test the linearity of the three aspects of the trilemma: monetary independence, exchange rate stability, and financial openness. We confirm that the weighted sum of the three trilemma policy variables adds up to a constant, validating the notion that a rise in one trilemma variable should be traded-off with a drop of the weighted sum of the other two. The second part of the paper deals with normative aspects of the trilemma, relating the policy choices to macroeconomic outcomes such as the volatility of output growth and inflation, and medium term inflation rates. Some key findings for developing countries include: (i) greater exchange rate stability implies greater output volatility, which can only be slightly mitigated by reserve accumulation; (ii) somewhat counter to previous findings, greater exchange rate stability is also associated with greater inflation volatility, and (iii) greater monetary autonomy is associated with a higher level of inflation. We believe these results differ from those identified in previous studies due to the comprehensive nature of our analysis, which encompasses more than 100 countries and 37 years, as well as the inclusion of a number of additional structural and policy variables in the regressions.
    JEL: F15 F21 F31 F36 F41 O24
    Date: 2008–12
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:14533&r=opm
  4. By: Ulf Söderström
    Abstract: I revisit the potential costs and benefits for Sweden of joining the Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) of the European Union. I first show that the Swedish business cycle since the mid-1990s has been closely correlated with the Euro area economies, suggesting that common shocks have been an important driving force of business cycles in Europe. However, evidence from an estimated model of the Swedish economy instead suggests that country-specific shocks have been important for fluctuations in the Swedish economy since 1993, implying that EMU membership could be costly. The model also indicates that the exchange rate has to a large extent acted to destabilize, rather than stabilize, the Swedish economy, pointing to the costs of independent monetary policy with a flexible exchange rate. Finally, counterfactual simulations of the model suggest that Swedish inflation and GDP growth might have been slightly higher if Sweden had been a member of EMU since the launch in 1999, but also that GDP growth might have been more volatile. The evidence is therefore not conclusive about whether or not participation in the monetary union would be advantageous for Sweden.
    JEL: E42 E58 F41
    Date: 2008–12
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:14519&r=opm
  5. By: Kenza Benhima
    Abstract: The paper shows that in a general equilibrium model with two countries, characterized by different levels of financial development, and two technologies, one more productive and more financially demanding than the other, the following stylized facts can be replicated: 1) the persistent US current account deficits since the beginning of the 90’s; 2) growth of output per worker in developing countries in relative terms with the US during the same period; 3) relative capital accumulation and 4) TFP growth in these countries, also relative to the US. The more productive technology takes more time to implement and is subject to liquidity shocks, while the less productive one, along with external bond assets, can be used as a hoard to finance those liquidity shocks. As a result, after financial globalization, if the emerging economy is capital scarce and if its financial market is sufficiently incomplete, it experiences an increase in net foreign assets that coincides with a fall in the less productive investment and a rise in the more productive one. Convergence towards the steady state implies then both a better allocation of capital that generates endogenous aggregate TFP gains and a rise in aggregate investment that translates into higher growth.
    Keywords: Growth, Capital flows, Credit constraints, financial globalization, technological change
    JEL: F36 F43 O16 O33
    Date: 2008
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:drm:wpaper:2008-26&r=opm
  6. By: Kenza Benhima
    Abstract: The neoclassical growth model predicts that emerging countries with higher TFP growth should receive larger capital inflows. Gourinchas and Jeanne (2007) document that, in fact, countries that exhibited higher productivity catch-up received less capital inflows, even though they invested more in their domestic technology. This is the allocation puzzle. I show that introducing investment risk in the same neoclassical framework reverses the predictions in terms of capital flows: countries with higher TFP growth invest more in their own production but they have to hold more external bonds in order to self-insure against investment risk, which is consistent with the data. Indeed, the introduction of risky investment makes the portfolio composition matters: instead of being identical assets, bond holdings and private capital become imperfect substitutes inside the portfolio.
    Keywords: Growth accounting, Capital flows, Investment risk, Financial globalization, Portfolio choice
    JEL: F21 F43 G11 O16
    Date: 2008
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:drm:wpaper:2008-27&r=opm
  7. By: Carlos Felipe Lopez Suarez; Jose Antonio Rodriguez Lopez (Department of Economics, University of California-Irvine)
    Abstract: We study whether the nonlinear behavior of the real exchange rate can help us account for the lack of predictability of the nominal exchange rate. We construct a smooth nonlinear error-correction model that allows us to test the hypotheses of nonlinear predictability of the nominal exchange rate and nonlinear behavior on the real exchange rate in the context of a fully specified cointegrated system. Using a panel of 19 countries and three numeraires, we find strong evidence of nonlinear predictability of the nominal exchange rate and of nonlinear mean reversion of the real exchange rate. Out-of-sample Theil's U-statistics show a higher forecast precision of the nonlinear model than the one obtained with a random walk specification. The statistical significance of the out-of-sample results is higher for short-run horizons, specially for one-quarter-ahead forecasts.
    Keywords: Exchange rates; Predictability; Nonlinearities; Purchasing power parity
    JEL: C53 F31 F47
    Date: 2008–12
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:irv:wpaper:080911&r=opm
  8. By: Domenico Giannone; Michele Lenza; Lucrezia Reichlin
    Abstract: This paper shows that the EMU has not affected historical characteristics of member countries’ business cycles and their cross-correlations. Member countries which had similar levels of GDP percapita in the seventies have also experienced similar business cycles since then and no significant change associated with the EMU can be detected. For the other countries, volatility has been historically higher and this has not changed in the last ten years. We also find that the aggregate euro area per-capita GDP growth since 1999 has been lower than what could have been predicted on the basis of historical experience and US observed developments. The gap between US and euro area GDP per capita level has been 30% on average since 1970 and there is no sign of catching up or of further widening.
    Keywords: Euro area, International Business Cycle, European monetary union, European integration
    JEL: E32 C5 F2 F43
    Date: 2008
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:eca:wpaper:2008_040&r=opm
  9. By: Jeffrey A. Frankel
    Abstract: Andy Rose (2000), followed by many others, has used the gravity model of bilateral trade on a large data set to estimate the trade effects of monetary unions among small countries. The finding has been large estimates: Trade among members seems to double or triple, that is, to increase by 100-200%. After the advent of EMU in 1999, Micco, Ordoñez and Stein and others used the gravity model on a much smaller data set to estimate the effects of the euro on trade among its members. The estimates tend to be statistically significant, but far smaller in magnitude: on the order of 10-20% during the first four years. What explains the discrepancy? This paper seeks to address two questions. First, do the effects on intra-euroland trade that were estimated in the euro's first four years hold up in the second four years? The answer is yes. Second, and more complicated, what is the reason for the big discrepancy vis-à-vis other currency unions? We investigate three prominent possible explanations for the gap between 15% and 200%. First, lags. The euro is still very young. Second, size. The European countries are much bigger on average than most of those who had formed currency unions in the past. Third, endogeneity of the decision to adopt an institutional currency link. Perhaps the high correlations estimated in earlier studies were spurious, an artifact of reverse causality. Contrary to expectations, we find no evidence that any of these factors explains a substantial share of the gap, let alone all of it.
    JEL: F01 F33 F4
    Date: 2008–12
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:14542&r=opm
  10. By: Domenico Giannone; Michele Lenza; Lucrezia Reichlin
    Abstract: This paper shows that the EMU has not affected historical characteristics of member countries' business cycles and their cross-correlations. Member countries which had similar levels of GDP per-capita in the seventies have also experienced similar business cycles since then and no significant change associated with the EMU can be detected. For the other countries, volatility has been historically higher and this has not changed in the last ten years. We also find that the aggregate euro area per-capita GDP growth since 1999 has been lower than what could have been predicted on the basis of historical experience and US observed developments. The gap between US and euro area GDP per capita level has been 30% on average since 1970 and there is no sign of catching up or of further widening.
    JEL: C5 E32 F2 F43
    Date: 2008–12
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:14529&r=opm
  11. By: Ricardo J. Caballero; Emmanuel Farhi; Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas
    Abstract: In this paper we argue that the persistent global imbalances, the subprime crisis, and the volatile oil and asset prices that followed it, are tightly interconnected. They all stem from a global environment where sound and liquid financial assets are in scarce supply.
    JEL: F3
    Date: 2008–12
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:14521&r=opm
  12. By: Weshah Razzak; Rabie Nasser
    Abstract: We use a variety of nonparametric test statistics to evaluate the inflation- targeting regimes of Australia, Canada, New Zealand, Sweden and the UK. We argue that a sensible approach of evaluation must rely on a variety of methods, among them parametric and nonparametric econometric methods, for robustness and completeness. Our evaluation strategy is based on examining two possible policy implications of inflation targeting: First, a welfare implication and second, a real variability implication. The welfare implication involves evaluating a utility function, and tested by testing whether (1) the distributions of the levels and the growth rates of private consumption and leisure per capita remained unchanged under inflation targeting, i.e., first-order stochastic dominance; and (2) testing a linear combination of consumption and leisure per capita, where the parameter describing the utility of leisure or the relative preference of leisure is calibrated. Then we introduce nonparametric univariate and multivariate statistical methods to test whether the first and second moments of a variety of real variables, such as the real exchange rate depreciation rate, real GDP per capita growth rate in addition to private consumption per capita and leisure per capita growth rates, remained unchanged under inflation targeting, decreased or increased significantly. There seems to be some evidence of increased welfare under inflation-targeting regimes, but no concrete evidence is found that inflation targeting policy, in general, reduces real variability. Some cross country differences are also found.
    Keywords: Nonparametric, First-order stochastic dominance, sudden shift in the distribution, inflation targeting.
    JEL: C02 C12 C14 E31
    Date: 2008–11–18
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:eei:rpaper:eeri_rp_2008_18&r=opm
  13. By: Joshua Aizenman; Reuven Glick
    Abstract: This paper presents statistical analysis supporting stylized facts about sovereign wealth funds (SWFs). It discusses the forces leading to the growth of SWFs, including the role of fuel exports and ongoing current account surpluses, and large hoarding of international reserves. It analyzes the degree to which measures of SWF governance and transparency compare with national norms of behavior. We provide evidence that many countries with SWFs are characterized by effective governance, but weak democratic institutions, as compared to other nonindustrial countries. We also present a model with which we compare the optimal degree of diversification abroad by a central bank versus that of a sovereign wealth fund. We show that if the central bank manages its foreign assets with the objective of reducing the probability of sudden stops, it will place a high weight on the downside risk of holding risky assets abroad and will tend to hold primarily safe foreign assets. In contrast, if the sovereign wealth fund, acting on behalf of the Treasury, maximizes the expected utility of a representative domestic agent, it will opt for relatively greater holding of more risky foreign assets. We discuss how the degree of a country's transparency may affect the size of the foreign asset base entrusted to a wealth fund's management, and show that, for relatively low levels of public foreign assets, assigning portfolio management independence to the central bank may be advantageous. However, for a large enough foreign asset base, the opportunity cost associated with the limited portfolio diversification of the central bank induces authorities to establish a wealth fund in pursuit of higher returns.
    JEL: E52 E58 F15 F3
    Date: 2008–12
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:14562&r=opm
  14. By: Kalina Manova
    Abstract: Three fundamental features of international trade flows are a predominance of zeros in the bilateral trade matrix, great variation in the number of products countries export, and substantial turnover in the product mix of exports over time. This paper provides evidence that credit constraints are an important determinant of all three patterns. I develop a model with credit-constrained heterogeneous firms, countries at different levels of financial development, and sectors of varying financial vulnerability, and find strong empirical support for the model's predictions. First, I show that financially developed countries are more likely to export bilaterally and ship greater volumes when they become exporters. This effect is more pronounced in sectors with a greater requirement for outside finance or fewer collateralizable assets. Firm selection into exporting accounts for a third of the effect of credit constraints on export volumes, whereas two thirds are due to the impact on firm-level exports. Second, in financially vulnerable sectors, financially developed countries export a wider variety of products and experience less product turnover in their exports over time. Finally, credit constraints lead to a pecking order of trade. While all countries export to large destinations, financially advanced countries have more trading partners and also export to smaller import markets, especially in financially vulnerable sectors.
    JEL: F10 F14 F36 G20 G28 G32
    Date: 2008–12
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:14531&r=opm
  15. By: Joshua Aizenman; Michael Hutchison; Ilan Noy
    Abstract: We examine the inflation targeting (IT) experiences of emerging market economies, focusing especially on the roles of the real exchange rate and the distinction between commodity and non-commodity exporting nations. In the context of a simple empirical model, estimated with panel data for 17 emerging markets using both IT and non-IT observations, we find a significant and stable response running from inflation to policy interest rates in emerging markets that are following publically announced IT policies. By contrast, central banks respond much less to inflation in non-IT regimes. IT emerging markets follow a “mixed IT strategy†whereby both inflation and real exchange rates are important determinants of policy interest rates. The response to real exchange rates is much stronger in non-IT countries, however, suggesting that policymakers are more constrained in the IT regime—they are attempting to simultaneously target both inflation and real exchange rates and these objectives are not always consistent. We also find that the response to real exchange rates is strongest in those countries following IT policies that are relatively intensive in exporting basic commodities. We present a simple model that explains this empirical result.
    JEL: E52 E58 F15 F3
    Date: 2008–12
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:14561&r=opm
  16. By: Döpke, J.; Funke, M.; Holly, S.; Weber, S.
    Abstract: In a standard dynamic stochastic general equilibrium framework, with sticky prices, the cross sectional distribution of output and inflation across a population of firms is studied. The only form of heterogeneity is confined to the probability that the ith firm changes its prices in response to a shock. In this Calvo setup the moments of the cross sectional distribution of output and inflation depend crucially on the proportion of firms that are allowed to change their prices. We test this model empirically using German balance sheet data on a very large population of firms. We find a significant counter-cyclical correlation between the skewness of output responses and the aggregate economy. Further analysis of sectoral data for the US suggests that there is a positive relationship between the skewness of inflation and aggregates, but the relation with output skewness is less sure. Our results can be interpreted as indirect evidence of the importance of price stickiness in macroeconomic adjustment.
    JEL: D12 E52 E43
    Date: 2008–09
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cam:camdae:0853&r=opm

This nep-opm issue is ©2008 by Martin Berka. It is provided as is without any express or implied warranty. It may be freely redistributed in whole or in part for any purpose. If distributed in part, please include this notice.
General information on the NEP project can be found at http://nep.repec.org. For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese at <director@nep.repec.org>. Put “NEP” in the subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.