nep-lab New Economics Papers
on Labour Economics
Issue of 2011‒08‒22
sixty-six papers chosen by
Stephanie Lluis
University of Waterloo

  1. Enforcement of Labor Regulation and Informality By Almeida, Rita K.; Carneiro, Pedro
  2. What Explains the German Labor Market Miracle in the Great Recession? By Burda, Michael C; Hunt, Jennifer
  3. On Educational Performance Measures By Muriel, Alastair; Smith, Jeffrey A.
  4. Comparative Essay on Returns to Education in Palestine and Turkey By Tansel, Aysit; Daoud, Yousef
  5. Comparative Essay on Returns to Education in Palestine and Turkey By Aysit Tansel; Yousef Daoud
  6. Exam High Schools and Academic Achievement: Evidence from New York City By Will Dobbie; Roland G. Fryer, Jr.
  7. Labor Markets and Labor Market Institutions in Transition Economies By Lehmann, Hartmut; Muravyev, Alexander
  8. "Employment Effects of the 2009 Minimum Wage Increase: Evidence from State Comparisons of At-Risk Workers (Revised Version)" By Saul D. Hoffman; Chenglong Ke
  9. Managerial Incentives and Compensation in a Global Market By Yanhui Wu
  10. Equilibrium Wage and Employment Dynamics in a Model of Wage Posting without Commitment By Coles, Melvyn; Mortensen, Dale T.
  11. Pro-cyclical Unemployment Benefits? Optimal Policy in an Equilibrium Business Cycle Model By Kurt Mitman; Stanislav Rabinovich
  12. Continuous Training, Job Satisfaction and Gender: An Empirical Analysis Using German Panel Data By Claudia Burgard; Katja Görlitz
  13. When more schooling is not worth the effort: another look at the dropout decisions of disadvantaged students in Uruguay. By Rossana Patrón
  14. Simultaneous Search and Network Efficiency By Gautier, Pieter A; Holzner, Christian
  15. What happens to the husband’s retirement decision when the wife’s retirement incentives change? By Selin, Håkan
  16. Equilibrium Wage and Employment Dynamics in a Model of Wage Posting without Commitment By Melvyn G. Coles; Dale T. Mortensen
  17. Labor Market Flows in the Cross Section and Over Time By Steven J. Davis; Jason Faberman; John C. Haltiwanger
  18. DO I BELONG HERE? Exploring Immigrant College Student Responses on the SERU Survey Sense of Belonging/Satisfaction Factor By Michael J. Stebleton, Ronald L. Huesman, Jr., Aliya Kuzhabekova
  19. The Signalling Role of Promotion in Japan By Kazuaki Okamura
  20. A Simple Theory of Managerial Talent, Pay Contracts and Wage Distribution By Yanhui Wu
  21. BEYOND THE MASTER PLAN: The Case for Restructuring Baccalaureate Education in California By Saul Geiser and Richard C. Atkinson
  22. Inequality of Opportunity in Educational Achievement in Latin America: Evidence from PISA 2006-2009 By Luis Fernando Gamboa; Fábio D. Waltenberg
  23. Public Expenditure on Education and Skill Formation: Is There a Simple Rule to Maximize Skills? By Rossana Patrón; Marcel Vaillant
  24. Does Unemployment Hurt Less if There Is More of It Around?: A Panel Analysis of Life Satisfaction in Germany and Switzerland By Daniel Oesch; Oliver Lipps
  25. Racial Discrimination and Competition By Ross Levine; Alexey Levkov; Yona Rubinstein
  26. How Competitive are Female Professionals? A Tale of Identity Conflict By Bram Cadsby; Maroš Servátka; Fei Song
  27. "Wage Inequality and the Labor Market Impact of Economic Transformation: Croatia, 1970-2008" By Saul D. Hoffman; Ivo Bicanic; Oriana Vukoja
  28. Low-Wage Import Competition, Inflationary Pressure,and Industry Dynamics in Europe By Raphael Anton Auer; Kathrin Degen; Andreas M. Fischer
  29. Does School Education Reduce the Likelihood of Societal Conflict in Africa? By Johannes Fedderke; Robert Klitgaard; Kamil Akramov
  30. Housewives in a dual-earner society Who is a housewife in contemporary Norway? By Ragni Hege Kitterød and Marit Rønsen
  31. R&D and Employment: Some Evidence from European Microdata By Bogliacino, Francesco; Piva, Mariacristina; Vivarelli, Marco
  32. RE-IMAGINING CALIFORNIA HIGHER EDUCATION By John Aubrey Douglass
  33. CONVERGENCE IN THE CANADIAN PROVINCES: EVIDENCE USING UNEMPLOYMENT RATES By Firouz Fallahi; Gabriel Rodríguez
  34. EXCELLENCE AND DIVERSITY: The Emergence of Selective Admission Policies in Dutch Higher Education - A Case Study on Amsterdam University College By Christoffel Reumer and Marijk van der Wende
  35. ACADEMIC DISCIPLINES AND THE UNDERGRADUATE EXPERIENCE: Rethinking Bok’s “Underachieving Colleges†Thesis By Steven Brint and Allison M. Cantwell
  36. Performance Pay and Information: Reducing Child Malnutrition in Urban Slums By Singh, Prakarsh
  37. Sports and Child Development By Felfe, Christina; Lechner, Michael; Steinmayr, Andreas
  38. Towards a Transnational Analysis of the Political Economy of Care By Williams, Fiona
  39. AFTER BROWNE: The New Competitive Regime for English Higher Education By Roger Brown
  40. Getting Progress Right: Measuring Progress Towards the MDGs Against Historical Trends By Stephan Klasen; Simon Lange
  41. "Social Security: Universal vs. Earnings-Dependent Benefits" By Jorge Soares
  42. Finding the benefits: Estimating the impact of the South African child support grant By Marisa Coetzee
  43. Life Expectancy and Schooling: New Insights from Cross-Country Data By Hazan, Moshe
  44. Would People Behave Differently If They Better Understood Social Security? Evidence From a Field Experiment By Jeffrey B. Liebman; Erzo F.P. Luttmer
  45. The Study of Compensation Systems Through the Lens of Self-Determination Theory: Reconciling 35 Years of Debate By Jacques Forest; Marylène Gagné
  46. THE MULTIDISCIPLIPLINARY IMPERATIVE IN HIGHER EDUCATION By C. Judson King
  47. Estimating the Permanent Growth Effects of Human Capital By Rao, Bhaskara; Shankar, Sriram
  48. Net migration and convergence in Portugal. An alternative analysis By Martinho, Vítor João Pereira Domingues
  49. Disentangling income inequality and the redistributive effect of social transfers and taxes in 36 LIS countries By Wang, Chen; Caminada, Koen
  50. The Experience of Unemployment in Ireland: A Thematic Analysis By Liam Delaney; Michael Egan; Nicola O'Connell
  51. Influence of age of child on differences in marital satisfaction of males and females in East Asian countries By Yamamura, Eiji; Andrés, Antonio
  52. TRENDS AND INNOVATIONS IN HIGHER EDUCATION REFORM: Worldwide, Latin America and in the Caribbean By Francisco López Segrera
  53. Structural Transformation and Productivity in Latin America By Silva, Leonardo Fonseca da; Ferreira, Pedro Cavalcanti
  54. A GLOBAL TALENT MAGNET: How a San Francisco/Bay Area Higher Education Hub Could Advance California’s Comparative Advantage In Attracting International Talent and Further Build US Economic Competitiveness By John Aubrey Douglass, Richard Edelstein and Cecile Hoareau
  55. The effect of the supplementary grant on parental contribution in the Netherlands By Roel van Elk
  56. HRM Practices and Performance of Family-Run Workplaces: Evidence from the 2004 WERS By Siebert, W. Stanley; Peng, Fei; Maimaiti, Yasheng
  57. Migration and Stratification By Jasso, Guillermina
  58. A Fair and Equitable Method of Recruitment? Conscription by Ballot into the Australian Army during the Vietnam War By Simon Ville; Peter Siminski
  59. Testable implications of economic revolutions: An application to historic data on European wages By Fry, J. M.; Masood, Omar
  60. SEEKING SUSTAINABLE PUBLIC UNIVERSITIES: The Legacy of the Great Recession By Katharine Lyall
  61. Family reunification or point-based immigration system? The case of the United States and Mexico By López Real, Joel
  62. Taxation and Regulation of Bonus Pay By Besley, Timothy J.; Ghatak, Maitreesh
  63. GLOBALIZATION AND DUAL MODES OF HIGHER EDUCATION POLICYMAKING IN FRANCE: Je t’aime moi non plus By Cécile Hoareau
  64. Alcohol Availability and Crime: Lessons from Liberalized Weekend Sales Restrictions By Grönqvist, Hans; Niknami, Susan
  65. DIVERSITY MATTERS: New Directions for Institutional Research on Undergraduate Racial/Ethnic and Economic Diversity By Gregg Thomson
  66. Parental Divorce and Generalized Trust By Viitanen, Tarja

  1. By: Almeida, Rita K. (World Bank); Carneiro, Pedro (University College London)
    Abstract: Enforcement of labor regulations in the formal sector may drive workers to informality because they increase the costs of formal labor. But better compliance with mandated benefits makes it attractive to be a formal employee. We show that, in locations with frequent inspections workers pay for mandated benefits by receiving lower wages. Wage rigidity prevents downward adjustment at the bottom of the wage distribution. As a result, lower paid formal sector jobs become attractive to some informal workers, inducing them to want to move to the formal sector.
    Keywords: informality, labor regulation
    JEL: J2 J3
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp5902&r=lab
  2. By: Burda, Michael C; Hunt, Jennifer
    Abstract: Germany experienced an even deeper fall in GDP in the Great Recession than the United States, with little employment loss. Employers’ reticence to hire in the preceding expansion, associated in part with a lack of confidence it would last, contributed to an employment shortfall equivalent to 40 percent of the missing employment decline in the recession. Another 20 percent may be explained by wage moderation. A third important element was the widespread adoption of working time accounts, which permit employers to avoid overtime pay if hours per worker average to standard hours over a window of time. We find that this provided disincentives for employers to lay off workers in the downturn. Although the overall cuts in hours per worker were consistent with the severity of the Great Recession, reduction of working time account balances substituted for traditional government-sponsored short-time work.
    Keywords: extensive vs intensive employment margin; Germany; Great Recession; Hartz reforms; short time work; unemployment; working time accounts
    JEL: E24 E32 J6
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cpr:ceprdp:8520&r=lab
  3. By: Muriel, Alastair (Institute for Fiscal Studies, London); Smith, Jeffrey A. (University of Michigan)
    Abstract: Quantitative school performance measures (QPMs) are playing an ever larger role in education systems on both sides of the Atlantic. In this paper we outline the rationale for the use of such measures in education, review the literature relating to several important problems associated with their use, and argue that they nonetheless have a positive role to play in improving the educational quality. We delineate several institutional reforms which would help schools to respond "positively" to QPMs, emphasizing the importance of agents' flexibility to change the way they work, and the importance of a sound knowledge base regarding "what works" in raising attainment. We suggest that the present institutional setups in both England and the US too often hold schools accountable for outcomes over which they have little control – but that such problems are far from insurmountable.
    Keywords: performance measures, education incentives, school quality
    JEL: H52 I2 I28
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp5897&r=lab
  4. By: Tansel, Aysit (Middle East Technical University); Daoud, Yousef (Birzeit University Palestine)
    Abstract: This study exposes a comparative treatment of the private returns to education in Palestine and Turkey over the period 2004-2008. Comparable data, similar definitions and same methodology are used in the estimations. The estimates are provided first for average returns to education second for returns at different levels of schooling and finally for returns by different sectors of employment. The results suggest that returns to schooling are higher for Turkey at the various levels of education for Females and males and for both years 2004 and 2008. It is believed that the relative size of the Palestinian economy the uniqueness of subjugation to military occupation contribute greatly to this result. In 2008, returns are lower than 2004 levels for all levels of education; the pattern is less obvious for Turkey across the various levels. However, the 2008 crisis seems to have influenced the more educated more severely (MA and above) in both countries. Female returns to education are higher for women than men in both countries; the gender gap has worsened in 2008, but more so for Palestine. The median ratio of male to female return is 0.55 (university) in 2004 and decreased to 0.17 (high school) in 2008 in Palestine. The corresponding figures for Turkey are 0.79 and .082 (both for high school).Finally, it was found that the selectivity corrected return estimates are lower than the OLS estimates in Palestine while they are higher than the OLS estimates in Turkey.
    Keywords: returns to education, Mincer equation, gender, Palestine, Turkey
    JEL: J16 J24 J31 J45 O31
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp5907&r=lab
  5. By: Aysit Tansel (Middle East Technical University and Economic Research Forum (ERF) Cairo, Egypt); Yousef Daoud (Birzeit University Palestine and Economic Research Forum (ERF) Cairo, Egypt)
    Abstract: This study exposes a comparative treatment of the private returns to education in Palestine and Turkey over the period 2004-2008. Comparable data, similar definitions and same methodology are used in the estimations. The estimates are provided first for average returns to education second for returns at different levels of schooling and finally for returns by different sectors of employment. The results suggest that returns to schooling are higher for Turkey at the various levels of education for females and males and for both years 2004 and 2008. It is believed that the relative size of the Palestinian economy and the uniqueness of subjugation to military occupation contribute greatly to this result. In 2008, returns are lower than 2004 levels for all levels of education; the pattern is less obvious for Turkey across the various levels. However, the 2008 crisis seems to have influenced the more educated more severely (MA and above) in both countries. Female returns to education are higher for women than men in both countries; the gender gap has worsened in 2008, but more so for Palestine. The median ratio of male to female return is 0.55 (university) in 2004 and decreased to 0.17 (high school) in 2008 in Palestine. The corresponding figures for Turkey are 0.79 and .082 (both for high school). Finally, it was found that the selectivity corrected return estimates are lower than the OLS estimates in Palestine while they are higher than the OLS estimates in Turkey.
    Keywords: Returns to Education, Mincer Equation, Gender, Palestine, Turkey
    JEL: J16 J24 J31 J45 O31
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:koc:wpaper:1118&r=lab
  6. By: Will Dobbie; Roland G. Fryer, Jr.
    Abstract: Publicly funded exam schools educate many of the world's most talented students. These schools typically contain higher achieving peers, more rigorous instruction, and additional resources compared to regular public schools. This paper uses a sharp discontinuity in the admissions process at three prominent exam schools in New York City to provide the first causal estimate of the impact of attending an exam school in the United States on longer term academic outcomes. Attending an exam school increases the rigor of high school courses taken and the probability that a student graduates with an advanced high school degree. Surprisingly, however, attending an exam school has little impact on Scholastic Aptitude Test scores, college enrollment, or college graduation -- casting doubt on their ultimate long term impact.
    JEL: I20 J00
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:17286&r=lab
  7. By: Lehmann, Hartmut (University of Bologna); Muravyev, Alexander (IZA)
    Abstract: This paper summarizes the evolution of labor markets and labor market institutions and policies in the countries of Central and Eastern Europe as well as of Central Asia over the last two decades. The main focus is on the evolution of labor market institutions, which are among candidate explanations for the very diverse trajectories of labor markets in the region. We consider recent contributions that attempt to assess the effect of labor market institutions on labor market performance of TEs, including the policy-relevant issue of complementarity of institutions.
    Keywords: transition economies, unemployment, labor market institutions, labor markets
    JEL: J21 P20
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp5905&r=lab
  8. By: Saul D. Hoffman (Department of Economics,University of Delaware); Chenglong Ke (Department of Economics,University of Delaware)
    Abstract: In July, 2009, the U.S. Federal minimum wage was increased from $6.55 to $7.25. Individuals in some states were unaffected by this increase, since the state minimum wage already exceeded $7.25. We use this variation to make comparisons of the employment of “at-risk” workers with their peers across states and with workers within states who were arguably unaffected by the increase. Our data come from the 2009 CPS, four and five months before and after the increase. We find little evidence of negative employment effects for teens or less- educated adults, but some stronger evidence of a negative effect for young adults with a high school degree or less. Control for demographic characteristics reduces the size and significance of the estimated effects.
    Keywords: Minimum Wage
    JEL: J08 J21 J38
    Date: 2011
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:dlw:wpaper:11-16.&r=lab
  9. By: Yanhui Wu
    Abstract: This paper embeds a principal-agent firm in an otherwise standard trade model a la Melitz (2003) to investigate the impact of globalization on the provision of managerial incentives and on the distribution of managerial compensation. Facing contractual frictions due to limited liability, firms with heterogeneous productivity endogenously sort into different pay structures to mitigate different levels of agency problems. More productive firms use a higher-powered incentive contract while less productive firms use a lowered- powered one. International trade within an industry enhances market competition, inducing resources reallocated from low productivity domestic firms to high productivity exporting .rms. The uneven effects of international trade on firms that differ in their exporting status and pay structure result in more prevalence of high-powered incentive pay, a larger wage gap between managers and production workers, and a higher level of wage inequality among managers.
    Keywords: trade, heterogeneous firms, pay contracts, managerial incentives, managerial compensation, wage inequality
    JEL: D2 F1 J3 L1
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cep:cepdps:dp1066&r=lab
  10. By: Coles, Melvyn (University of Essex); Mortensen, Dale T. (Northwestern University)
    Abstract: A rich but tractable variant of the Burdett-Mortensen model of wage setting behavior is formulated and a dynamic market equilibrium solution to the model is defined and characterized. In the model, firms cannot commit to wage contracts. Instead, the Markov perfect equilibrium to the wage setting game, characterized by Coles (2001), is assumed. In addition, firm recruiting decisions, firm entry and exit, and transitory firm productivity shocks are incorporated into the model. Given that the cost of recruiting workers is proportional to firm employment, we establish the existence of an equilibrium solution to the model in which wages are not contingent on firm size but more productive employers always pay higher wages. Although the state space, the distribution of workers over firms, is large in the general case, it reduces to a scalar that can be interpreted as the unemployment rate in the special case of homogenous firms. Furthermore, the equilibrium is unique. As the dimension of the state space is equal to the number of firms types in general, an (approximate) equilibrium is computable.
    Keywords: wage dispersion, wage setting, rank-preserving equilibrium
    JEL: D21 D49 E23 J42 J64
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp5900&r=lab
  11. By: Kurt Mitman (Department of Economics, University of Pennsylvania); Stanislav Rabinovich (Department of Economics, University of Pennsylvania)
    Abstract: We study the optimal provision of unemployment insurance (UI) over the business cycle. We use an equilibrium search and matching model with aggregate shocks to labor productivity, incorporating risk-averse workers, endogenous worker search effort decisions, and unemployment benefit expiration. We characterize the optimal UI policy, allowing both the benefit level and benefit duration to depend on the history of past aggregate shocks. We find that the optimal benefit is decreasing in current productivity and decreasing in current unemployment. Following a drop in productivity, benefits initially rise in order to provide short-run relief to the unemployed and stabilize wages, but then fall significantly below their pre-recession level, in order to speed up the subsequent recovery. Under the optimal policy, the path of benefits is pro-cyclical overall. As compared to the existing US UI system, the optimal history-dependent benefits smooth cyclical fluctuations in unemployment and deliver substantial welfare gains.
    Keywords: Unemployment Insurance, Business Cycles, Optimal Policy, Search and Matching
    JEL: E24 E32 H21 J65
    Date: 2011–08–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pen:papers:11-023&r=lab
  12. By: Claudia Burgard; Katja Görlitz
    Abstract: Using data from the German Socio-Economic Panel (SOEP), this paper analyzes the relationship between training and job satisfaction focusing in particular on gender differences. Controlling for a variety of socio-demographic, job and firm characteristics, we find a difference between males and females in the correlation of training with job satisfaction which is positive for males but insignificant for females. This difference becomes even more pronounced when applying individual fixed effects. To gain insights into the reasons for this difference, we further investigate training characteristics by gender. We find that financial support and career-orientation of courses only seems to matter for the job satisfaction of men but not of women.
    Keywords: Training, job satisfaction, gender differences, fixed effects
    JEL: I29 J24 J28 M53
    Date: 2011
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:diw:diwsop:diw_sp394&r=lab
  13. By: Rossana Patrón (Departamento de Economía, Facultad de Ciencias Sociales, Universidad de la República)
    Abstract: In Uruguay, similar to many developing countries, the economic return to lower secondary studies is low. When heterogeneity is introduced in the analysis, it can be shown that differences in the quality of education and in the probability of repetition mark the contrast between an attractive and an inconvenient investment in secondary education between advantaged and disadvantaged students. The values of internal rate of return computed for the Uruguayan case allow concluding that, paradoxically, lower secondary education is an inconvenient investment for disadvantaged students, even disregarding the possibility of them not being able to afford the opportunity costs, explaining the heavy dropout rates of this student type. These results cast some serious doubts on the fairness of compulsory schooling laws that are not accompanied by complementary policies to ensure equal learning outcomes across socioeconomic groups.
    Keywords: education returns, school quality, repetition rates
    JEL: I21 J24
    Date: 2011–02
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ude:wpaper:0511&r=lab
  14. By: Gautier, Pieter A; Holzner, Christian
    Abstract: When workers send applications to vacancies they create a network. Frictions arise if workers do not know where other workers apply to (this affects network creation) and firms do not know which candidates other firms consider (this affects network clearing). We show that those frictions and the wage mechanism are in general not independent. Equilibria that exhibit wage dispersion are inefficient in terms of network formation. Under complete recall (firms can go back and forth between all their candidates) only wage mechanisms that allow for ex post Bertrand competition generate the maximum matching on a realized network.
    Keywords: Efficiency; network clearing; random bipartite network formation; simultaneous search
    JEL: D83 D85 E24 J64
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cpr:ceprdp:8522&r=lab
  15. By: Selin, Håkan (Uppsala Center for Fiscal Studies)
    Abstract: Several studies have documented a strong correlation in the timing of spouses’ retirement decisions. However, considerably less is known about the causal impact of one spouse’s retirement incentives on the retirement decision of the other spouse. Before, but not after, 2001 broad categories of Swedish local government workers in female dominated occupations were entitled to retire with full pension benefits already at the age of 63. In this paper, we utilize this reform – together with a micro data set covering the total Swedish population – to estimate the effect of a change in the wife’s incentive on the husband’s retirement behavior. We document a sharp decrease in pension benefit withdrawals among 63 year old wives in the local government sector in the years following the reform. However, we do not find any evidence of a response among husbands. This finding is at odds with some earlier results in the literature.
    Keywords: Joint retirement; retirement age; occupational pensions
    JEL: H55 J13 J21
    Date: 2011–07–11
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hhs:uufswp:2011_008&r=lab
  16. By: Melvyn G. Coles; Dale T. Mortensen
    Abstract: A rich but tractable variant of the Burdett-Mortensen model of wage setting behavior is formulated and a dynamic market equilibrium solution to the model is defined and characterized. In the model, firms cannot commit to wage contracts. Instead, the Markov perfect equilibrium to the wage setting game, characterized by Coles (2001), is assumed. In addition, firm recruiting decisions, firm entry and exit, and transitory firm productivity shocks are incorporated into the model. Given that the cost of recruiting workers is proportional to firm employment, we establish the existence of an equilibrium solution to the model in which wages are not contingent on firm size but more productive employers always pay higher wages. Although the state space, the distribution of workers over firms, is large in the general case, it reduces to a scalar that can be interpreted as the unemployment rate in the special case of homogenous firms. Furthermore, the equilibrium is unique. As the dimension of the state space is equal to the number of firms types in general, an (approximate) equilibrium is computable.
    JEL: D83 E24 J31 J6
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:17284&r=lab
  17. By: Steven J. Davis; Jason Faberman; John C. Haltiwanger
    Abstract: Many theoretical models of labor market search imply a tight link between worker flows (hires and separations) and job gains and losses at the employer level. Partly motivated by these theories, we exploit establishment-level data from U.S. sources to study the relationship between worker flows and job flows in the cross section and over time. We document strong, highly nonlinear relationships of hiring, quit and layoff rates to employer growth in the cross section. Simple statistical models that capture these cross-sectional relationships greatly improve our ability to account for fluctuations in aggregate worker flows. We also evaluate how well various theoretical models and views fit the patterns in the data. Aggregate fluctuations in layoffs are well captured by micro specifications that impose a tight cross-sectional link between worker flows and job flows. Aggregate fluctuations in quits are not. Instead, quit rates rise and fall with booms and recessions across the distribution of establishment growth rates, but more so at shrinking employers. Finally, we use our preferred statistical models – in combination with data on the cross-sectional distribution of establishment growth rates – to construct synthetic JOLTS-type measures of hires, separations, quits and layoffs back to 1990.
    JEL: E24 J63 J64
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:17294&r=lab
  18. By: Michael J. Stebleton, Ronald L. Huesman, Jr., Aliya Kuzhabekova
    Abstract: The immigrant college student population will likely continue to increase. This exploratory study addresses the questions: To what extent does sense of belonging/satisfaction of recent immigrant college students differ from non-immigrant college students? Do perceived self-ratings of belonging vary by immigrant generations? This research draws on a new extensive data source, the Student Experience in the Research University (SERU) survey. Survey data from the 2009 SERU is based on the responses from 55,433 undergraduate students from six-large research institutions from across the United States. Findings suggest that immigrant students’ perception of their sense of belonging and satisfaction is significantly lower than their non-immigrant peers’ perceptions. Immigrant college students -- whether they were a recent immigrant that arrived in the country as a child, or arrived later as a teenager or young adult, or are the children of parents born outside the U.S. ( 2nd generation) -- consistently reported lower levels of belonging/satisfaction as compared to their 3rd or 4th generation (i.e., nonimmigrant) peers. Responses within the immigrant generation groups were similar. The following implications were highlighted: effective practice and application strategies for student affairs practitioners and faculty members who work directly with immigrant college students; policy development suggestions for both academic and student affairs administrators; future research inquiries for scholars who are interested in this fast growing population of college students.
    Keywords: Education
    Date: 2010–09–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cdl:cshedu:2127926&r=lab
  19. By: Kazuaki Okamura (Department of Economics and Social Sciences, Faculty of Humanities and Economics, Kochi University)
    Abstract: Under asymmetric information conditions regarding worker productivity between current and prospective employers, a worker's promotion signals his/her productivity. In this Paper, we tested the signalling role of promotion, using Japanese micro-level data. We found that among lower-level positions, promotion seems to signal a worker's ability, and both the business cycle and foreign-capital ratio of his/her company significantly strengthen this effects. These results suggest that external labour market conditions (i.e. asymmetric information regarding a worker's abilities between a current and prospective employer) affect the economic differences among workers in the internal labour market.
    Keywords: Strategically delayed promotion, Signalling, Wage growth, Japan.
    JEL: C23 J31 L22
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:koe:wpaper:1112&r=lab
  20. By: Yanhui Wu
    Abstract: This paper develops a simple theory of pay structures and pay levels across heterogeneous agents by bringing together optimal contracts inside the firm and competitive resource allocation in the market. The central idea is that more talented people tend to create greater value but face larger conflicts of interest in their employment relationship, and different pay contracts are optimally designed to mitigate different levels of agency problems. Sorted by their talent, people are stratified into production workers, self-employed, salaried managers with low-powered performance pay, and CEOs with high-powered equity-based pay. In a general equilibrium framework, I show that the sorting of managerial talent into pay contracts is tied to firm size. The theory highlights that high-powered incentive pay and large scales of operations cause the disproportionately large wage earnings at the top, and are the main source of income inequality. Market forces that reallocate resources from smaller to larger firms tend to increase the threshold talent for becoming a manager, increase the prevalence of high-powered incentive pay, raise the top earnings, and spread out the wage distribution.
    Keywords: Managerial Talent, Limited Liability, Provision of Incentives, Pay Structure, CEOPay, Wage Distribution
    JEL: D2 J3 L1 L2 M5
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cep:cepdps:dp1067&r=lab
  21. By: Saul Geiser and Richard C. Atkinson
    Abstract: Although a stunning success in many ways, California’s 1960 Master Plan for Higher Education has been a conspicuous failure in one respect: California ranks near the bottom of the states in the proportion of its college-age population that attains a baccalaureate degree. California’s poor record of B.A. attainment is an unforeseen consequence of the Master Plan’s restrictions on access to 4-year baccalaureate institutions. In a cost-cutting move, the framers of the Master Plan restricted eligibility for admission to the University of California and the state colleges (later the California State University) to the top eighth and top third, respectively, of the state’s high school graduates. As a result, 2-year institutions have absorbed the vast majority of enrollment growth in California higher education. In addition to their important role in vocational education, the California Community Colleges now enroll between 40% and 50% of all students seeking a B.A., including those at both 2-year and 4-year institutions. Enrollment at 4-year institutions, however, has not kept pace. California now ranks last among the states in the proportion of its college students that attend a 4-year institution. The paper presents comparative data demonstrating the powerful relationship between 4-year college enrollment and B.A. attainment across the 50 states. Although California’s low rate of baccalaureate attainment is sometimes blamed on the failure of community colleges to produce more transfers, the data point to a more fundamental problem -- lack of 4-year baccalaureate enrollment capacity. The single most critical factor for California to improve B.A. attainment is to expand 4-year enrollment capacity. Yet building expensive new 4-year campuses is an unlikely option given the state’s current and foreseeable fiscal circumstances. The alternative is to restructure California’s existing postsecondary system. The paper reviews a variety of baccalaureate reform models that have been introduced in other states. The most promising of these models involve collaborations between community colleges and state universities to create new kinds of intermediary, “hybrid†institutions. Examples include university centers and 2-year university branch campuses. Under the university center model, 4-year universities offer upper-division coursework at community college campuses, enabling “place bound†students to complete their baccalaureate degree program there. Under the 2-year university branch model, some community colleges are converted, in effect, into lower-division satellites of state universities, thereby expanding capacity at the 4-year level and eliminating the need for the traditional transfer process. What these and other hybrid models have in common is that they help bridge the divide between 2-year and 4-year institutions, enabling more students to enter baccalaureate programs directly from high school and progress seamlessly to their degrees. Amending the Master Plan in the manner proposed here need not alter its essential features. While preserving the distinctive missions of UC, CSU, and the California Community Colleges, the need now is to build their capacity to work together as a system to improve baccalaureate attainment – the one mission that all three segments share.
    Keywords: Education
    Date: 2010–11–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cdl:cshedu:2127936&r=lab
  22. By: Luis Fernando Gamboa; Fábio D. Waltenberg
    Abstract: We assess inequality of opportunity in educational achievement in six Latin American countries, employing two waves of PISA data (2006 and 2009). By means of a non-parametric approach using a decomposable inequality index, GE(0), we rank countries according to their degree of inequality of opportunity. We work with alternative characterizations of types: school type (public or private), gender, parental education, and combinations of those variables. We calculate "incremental contributions" of each set of circumstances to inequality. We provide rankings of countries based on unconditional inequalities (using conventional indices) and on conditional inequalities (EOp indices), and the two sets of rankings do not always coincide. Inequality of opportunities range from less than 1% to up to 27%, with substantial heterogeneity according to the year, the country, the subject and the specificication of circumstances. Robustness checks based on bootstrap and the use of an alternative index confirm most of the initial results.
    Date: 2011–08–15
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:col:000092:008895&r=lab
  23. By: Rossana Patrón (Departamento de Economía, Facultad de Ciencias Sociales, Universidad de la República); Marcel Vaillant (Departamento de Economía, Facultad de Ciencias Sociales, Universidad de la República)
    Abstract: The ratio of skill to unskilled labour stocks in the economy is widely acknowledged to have an important role for development. Can education policy affect the evolution of this ratio? This paper shows that it can, and it also shows that the actual effect of education policy depends on the allocation rule of the budget across educational levels. The consideration of a stylized hierarchical education model allows us to develop analytical conditions under which the allocation rule favours the accumulation of skills. The analysis has implication for policy makers in developing countries, where skill formation is much needed, because it shows that observed allocation rules usually violate the maximization condition by the assignment of higher-than-optimal resources to higher education.
    Keywords: education budget, skills accumulation
    JEL: I21 I22 I2
    Date: 2011–02
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ude:wpaper:0611&r=lab
  24. By: Daniel Oesch; Oliver Lipps
    Abstract: This paper examines the existence of a habituation effect to unemployment: Do the unemployed suffer less from job loss if unemployment is more widespread, if their own unemployment lasts longer and if unemployment is a recurrent experience? The underlying idea is that unemployment hysteresis may operate through a sociological channel: if many people in the community lose their job and remain unemployed over an extended period, the psychological cost of being unemployed diminishes and the pressure to accept a new job declines. We analyze this question with individual-level data from the German Socio-Economic Panel (1984-2009) and the Swiss Household Panel (2000-2009). We find no evidence for a mitigating effect of high surrounding unemployment on unemployed individuals¿ subjective well-being: Becoming unemployed hurts as much when regional unemployment is high as when it is low. Likewise, the strongly harmful impact of being unemployed on well-being does not wear off over time, nor do repeated episodes of unemployment make it any better. It thus appears doubtful that an unemployment shock becomes persistent because the unemployed become used to, and hence reasonably content with, being without a job.
    Keywords: Subjective well-being, unemployment, hysteresis, happiness, social norm
    Date: 2011
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:diw:diwsop:diw_sp393&r=lab
  25. By: Ross Levine; Alexey Levkov; Yona Rubinstein
    Abstract: We provide the first assessment of whether an intensification of product market competition reduces the racial wage gap exactly where taste-based theories predict that competition will reduce labor market discrimination. in economies where employers have strong racial prejudices. We use bank deregulation across the U.S. states to identify an intensification of competition among banks, which in turn lowered entry barriers facing nonfinancial firms, especially firms that depend heavily on bank credit. Consistent with taste-based theories, we find that competition boosted blacks' relative residual wages within the banking industry and bank-dependent industries, but only in states with strong tastes for discrimination.
    Keywords: Discrimination, imperfect competition, banks, regulation
    JEL: J7 J31 D43 D3 G21 G28
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cep:cepdps:dp1069&r=lab
  26. By: Bram Cadsby; Maroš Servátka (University of Canterbury); Fei Song
    Abstract: We develop and test experimentally the argument that gender/family and/or professional identities, activated through psychological priming, may influence preference for competition. We focus on female professionals for whom these identities may conflict and male professionals for whom they may be reinforcing. We primed MBA-student participants by administering questionnaires that concerned either gender/family or professional issues. Subsequently, participants undertook a real-effort task and chose between piece-rate and competitive-tournament compensation. Identity priming, moderated by gender, significantly affected preference for competitive pay. This relationship was partially mediated by beliefs about one‟s performance ranking. The implications of our results are profound. The decision to avoid competition made by many female professionals may be driven not by lack of ability, but rather by the increased salience of gender/family identity, influenced by marriage and motherhood over time. Indeed, activation of internalized identities might not only drive the experimental results, but also have strong implications for career choices and job performance of women, thus contributing to the observed gender and motherhood wage gaps.
    Date: 2011–08–02
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cbt:econwp:11/31&r=lab
  27. By: Saul D. Hoffman (Department of Economics,University of Delaware); Ivo Bicanic (Department of Economics,University of Zagreb); Oriana Vukoja (Department of Economics,University of Zagreb)
    Abstract: In this paper, we examine wage inequality and wage differentials in Croatia from 1970 to 2008 using two long aggregate time series on the distribution of income. We focus especially on changing income inequality related to educational and vocational attainment, changing income inequality within those groups, and how these two components of inequality were affected by the economic transformation from Socialism to capitalism. We find that income inequality between groups rose moderately post-transformation, while overall inequality increased more sharply. This finding is consistent with a growing importance of individual rather than group productivity in labor market compensation, a change broadly consistent with the economic transformation of the Croatian labor market.
    Keywords: Croatia, Economics of Transition, Inequality, Gini coefficient
    JEL: J3 P2 P23
    Date: 2011
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:dlw:wpaper:11-17.&r=lab
  28. By: Raphael Anton Auer; Kathrin Degen; Andreas M. Fischer
    Abstract: What is the impact of import competition from low-wage countries (LWCs) on inflationary pressure in Europe? This paper examines whether labor-intensive exports from emerging Europe, Asia, and other global regions have a uniform impact on producer prices in Germany, France, Italy, Sweden, and the United Kingdom. In a panel covering 110 (4-digit) NACE industries from 1995 to 2008, instrumental variable estimations predict that LWC import competition is associated with strong price effects. More specifically, when LWC exporters capture 1% of European market share, producer prices decrease by about 3%. In contrast, no effect is present for import competition from low-wage countries in Central and Eastern Europe. Next, decomposing the mechanisms that underlie the LWC price effect on European industry, we show that import competition has a pronounced effect on average productivity and only a muted effect on wages. Owing to the exit of firms and the increase in productivity, LWC import competition is shown to have substantially reduced employment in the European manufacturing sector.
    Keywords: intra-industry trade, comparative advantage, globalization
    JEL: F11 F12 F14 F16 F40
    Date: 2011
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:snb:snbwpa:2011-09&r=lab
  29. By: Johannes Fedderke; Robert Klitgaard; Kamil Akramov
    Abstract: Heterogeneity Happens: How Rights Matter in Economic Development
    JEL: O10 D99
    Date: 2011
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:rza:wpaper:220&r=lab
  30. By: Ragni Hege Kitterød and Marit Rønsen (Statistics Norway)
    Abstract: The number of housewives has declined significantly in most Western countries, but there is now a renewed interest in the homemaker role in the media and public discourse. Utilising representative survey data from 2007 we examine the prevalence and characteristics of the housewife role in present Norway, a social-democratic country with high gender-equality ambitions. Irrespective of the definition used, being a housewife is clearly a minority practice in Norway. About one out of ten partnered women of prime working age either look upon themselves as housewives or work for pay less than 20 hours per week. Housewives are overrepresented among the less educated, those with health restrictions, women with many children and young children, non-Western immigrants and those with a partner with fairly high income. The partners’ aggregate income is lower in housewife couples than in other couples, though. Housewives are usually in charge of most domestic chores and report high levels of satisfaction with their division of labour and domestic economy. The analysis does not support the popular notion that today’s housewife is primarily a highly educated woman who puts her career on halt, or a rich man’s wife who spends her time on leisure activities.
    Keywords: Housewife; gender; equality; labour market; unpaid work.
    JEL: J13 J21 J22 J23
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ssb:dispap:659&r=lab
  31. By: Bogliacino, Francesco (Universidad EAFIT); Piva, Mariacristina (Università Cattolica del Sacro Cuore); Vivarelli, Marco (Università Cattolica del Sacro Cuore)
    Abstract: After discussing theory regarding the consequences of technological change on employment and surveying previous microeconometric literature, our aim with this paper is to test the possible job creation effect of business R&D expenditures, using a unique longitudinal database covering 677 European manufacturing and service firms over the period 1990-2008. The main outcome from the whole sample dynamic LSDVC (Least Squared Dummy Variable Corrected) estimate is the labour-friendly nature of companies’ R&D, the coefficient of which turns out to be statistically significant, although not very large in magnitude. However, the positive and significant impact of R&D expenditures on employment is detectable in services and high-tech manufacturing but absent in the more traditional manufacturing sectors. This means that we should not expect positive employment effects from increasing R&D in the majority of industrial sectors. This is something that should be borne in mind by European innovation policy makers having employment as one of their specific aims.
    Keywords: innovation, employment, manufacturing, services, LSDVC
    JEL: O33
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp5908&r=lab
  32. By: John Aubrey Douglass
    Abstract: 2010 marks the 50th anniversary of California’s famed Master Plan for Higher Education, arguably the single most influential effort to plan the future of a system of higher education in the annals of American higher education. This essay builds on the analysis offered in a previous CSHE research paper (“From Chaos to Order and Backâ€) by discussing the major challenges facing California’s higher education system, and offering a possibly pathway to reforms and institution-building essential for bolstering socioeconomic mobility and greater economic competitiveness. Most critics and observers of California’s system remain focused on incremental and largely marginal improvements, transfixed by the state’s persistent financial problems and inability to engage in long-range planning for a population that is projected to grow from approximately 37 million to some 60 million by 2050. President Obama has set a national goal for the US to once again have among the highest educational attainment rates in the world. This would require the nation to produce over 8 million additional degrees; California’s “fair share†would be approximately 1 million additional degrees. A number of studies indicate that California’s higher education system will not keep pace with labor needs in the state, let alone affording opportunities for socioeconomic mobility that once characterized California. California needs to re-imagine its once vibrant higher education system. The objective is to offer a vision of a more mature system of higher education that could emerge over the next twenty years; in essence, a logical next stage in a system that has hardly changed in the last five decades. Informed by the history of the tripartite system, its strengths and weaknesses over time, and the reform efforts of economic competitors throughout the world who are making significant investments in their own tertiary institutions, I offer a “re-imagined†network of colleges and universities and a plan for “Smart Growth.†I paint a picture that builds on California’s existing institutions, predicated on a more diverse array of institutional types, and rooted in the historical idea of mission differentiation. This includes setting educational attainment goals for the state; shifting more students to 4-year institutions including UC and CSU; reorganizing the California Community Colleges to include a set of 4-year institutions, another set of “Transfer Focused†campuses, and having these colleges develop a “gap†year program for students out of high school to better prepare for higher education. It also encompasses creating a new Polytechnic University sector, a new California Open University that is primarily focused on adult learners; and developing a new funding model that recognizes the critical role of tuition, and the market for international students that can generate income for higher education and attract top talent to California. There is also a need to recognize that for the US to increase degree attainment rates, the federal government will need to become a more engaged partner with the states. For the near and possibly long-term, most state governments are in a fiscally weakened position that makes any large-scale investment in expanding access improbable. Because of the size of its population alone, California is the canary in the coal mine. If the US is to make major strides toward President Obama’s goal, it cannot do it without California.
    Keywords: Education
    Date: 2010–10–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cdl:cshedu:2127930&r=lab
  33. By: Firouz Fallahi (University of Tabriz, Irán); Gabriel Rodríguez (Departamento de Economía - Pontificia Universidad Católica del Perú)
    Abstract: Quarterly time series data from Canada and the Canadian provinces for the period 1976:1-2005:3 are examined to determine if the unemployment rates in the Canadian provinces are converging to the national rate of unemployment. Firstly, we check for existence of stochastic convergence using recent unit root statistics, see Perron and Rodríguez (2003) and Rodríguez (2007). Secondly, we verify for existence of ??convergence using recently proposed methods by Vogel-sang (1998), Perron and Yabu (2009a, 2009b), and Bai and Perron (1998, 2003).Results from di¤erent unit root tests, without and with structural breaks, confirm that stochastic convergence exists in all provinces except British Columbia.The other results show strong evidence that deterministic convergence exists and the unemployment rates of the Canadian provinces are converging to the un-employment rate of Canada. This conclusion is stronger when multiple breaks are allowed in the trend function using the approach of Bai and Perron (1998,2003).
    Keywords: Stochastic convergence, -convergence, unit roots, structural breaks,unemployment.
    JEL: C22 O40 R00
    Date: 2011
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pcp:pucwps:wp00322&r=lab
  34. By: Christoffel Reumer and Marijk van der Wende
    Abstract: This paper explores the emergence of selective admission policies in Dutch university education. Such policies are being developed to promote excellence in a higher education system that is generally known to be “egalitarian†and increasingly criticized for a lack of differentiation. The changing policy context of admission in Dutch university education and its driving forces and rationales are discussed in the context of European-wide developments such as the Bologna Process. Especially the emergence of selective liberal arts colleges will be presented as a recent excellence initiative. A review of international trends, methods and criteria in selective admission (notably from systems with extensive experience in this field such as the USA), including historical pitfalls, provides an analytical framework for the discussion of the fostering of excellence in combination with the aim for diversity in the student population. The predictive value of selection methods and criteria used at Amsterdam University College (AUC) are evaluated against the study progress and performance of AUC students. This includes academic criteria such as GPA in secondary school, and AUC’s use of interviews. Examining data from AUC’s first entering class in 2009, the college has achieved enrolling students from different national and socioeconomic backgrounds. It is also achieving excellence in terms of study progress and academic performance, including an attrition rate of only 13 percent. The question is whether interviews generate sufficient added value, in particular with regard to the time and costs of this model and with a view to the risk of subjective interpretations of “soft variables†such as student motivation. The answer seems to be that interviews provide extra guidance to both the student and the institution as to whether the student is choosing the right study programme (and not so much as whether he or she is able to complete it successfully). Consequently, the combined model of selection on the basis of prior academic achievement at secondary school (GPA) and personal interviews will be continued. However, specific attention needs to be paid to the fact that the interviewer’s estimate of academic performance seems to be less accurate to predict study success than the actual secondary school GPA (i.e. based on the former more students could have been wrongly rejected than on the basis of the latter).
    Keywords: Education
    Date: 2010–10–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cdl:cshedu:2127932&r=lab
  35. By: Steven Brint and Allison M. Cantwell
    Abstract: Using data from the 2008 University of California Undergraduate Experience Survey, we show that study time and academic conscientiousness were lower among students in humanities and social science majors than among students in science and engineering majors. Analytical and critical thinking experiences were no more evident among humanities and social sciences majors than among science and engineering majors. All three academically beneficial experiences were, however, strongly related to participation in class and interaction with instructors, and participation was more common among humanities and social sciences students than among science and engineering students. Bok’s (2006) influential discussion of “underachievement’ in undergraduate education focused on institutional performance. Our findings indicate that future discussions should take into account differences among disciplinary categories and majors as well.
    Keywords: Education
    Date: 2011–03–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cdl:cshedu:2127961&r=lab
  36. By: Singh, Prakarsh
    Abstract: This paper provides evidence for the effectiveness of performance pay to government workers and how performance pay interacts with demand-side information. In an experiment covering 145 child day-care centres, I implement three separate treatments. First, I engineer an exogenous change in compensation for childcare workers from fixed wages to performance pay. Second, I only provide mothers with information without incentivizing the workers. Third, I combine the first two treatments. This helps us identify if performance pay and public information are complements or substitutes in reducing child malnutrition. I find that combining incentives to workers and information to mothers reduces weight-for-age malnutrition by 4.2% in 3 months, although individually the effects are negligible. This complementarity is shown to be driven by better mother-worker communication and the mother feeding more calorific food at home. There is also a sustained long-run positive impact of the combined treatment after the experiment concluded.
    Keywords: Performance pay; Child malnutrition; Public health; Information; Complementarity; Nutrition; Public sector; Urban slums
    JEL: J13 I12 H41 M52 L38 D12 H75 I18 I38 D61 J33
    Date: 2011–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:29403&r=lab
  37. By: Felfe, Christina; Lechner, Michael; Steinmayr, Andreas
    Abstract: Despite the relevance of cognitive and non-cognitive skills for professional success, their formation is not yet fully understood. This study fills part of this gap by analyzing the role of sports club participation, one of the most popular extra-curricular activities, on children’s skill development. Our results indicate positive effects: school performance improves by 0.20 standard deviations and overall non-cognitive skills by 0.09 standard deviations. The results are robust when using alternative datasets as well as alternative estimation and identification strategies. The effects can be partially explained by increased physical activities replacing passive leisure activities.
    Keywords: non-cognitive skills; physical activity; semi-parametric estimation; Skill formation
    JEL: J12 J13 J24
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cpr:ceprdp:8523&r=lab
  38. By: Williams, Fiona (Stockholm University Linnaeus Center for Integration Studies - SULCIS)
    Abstract: The resurgence of the employment of domestic and care workers in private homes in many industrialised countries over the last two decades has been shaped by important social changes, most notable among this are the increased responsibilities and rights of women across the globe to be both earners and carers. This reflects graduated shifts from the ‘male breadwinner’ to ‘adult worker’ model taking place in many industrialised societies and unemployment and poverty in developing countries. As many of those who carry out this work are migrant women, this reveals the movement of women seeking opportunities created by the changing patterns of post-colonial migration to financially support their families. Such migrations are also structured by the policies developed by states in richer countries. The nature of care regimes in host countries clearly influence take up: where care provision is commodified and where care cultures favour home-based/ surrogate care, then reliance on the low paid end of the private market is more common (Ungerson and Yeandle, 2007; Williams and Gavanas, 2008). At the same time, migration rules construct the legal, social and civil rights of migrants in different ways, in tandem with employment policies that may serve to deregulate the economy and to increase the casualisation of labour. Superimposed on this universe of change is the ongoing reconstitution of social relations of gender, care and domestic service, of hierarchies of ethnicity and nationality, and of differentiated meanings of, and rights to, citizenship. This paper draws on earlier research into migration and home-based care in Europe as a basis for developing a transnational analysis of the political economy of care (Lister et al, 2007, chapter 5; Williams and Gavanas, 2008; Williams, 2007; 2008; Williams, Tobio and Gavanas, 2009; Williams, 2010).
    Keywords: Care; Gender; Domestic Service; Ethnicity; Nationality
    JEL: J29 J61
    Date: 2011–08–09
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hhs:sulcis:2011_006&r=lab
  39. By: Roger Brown
    Abstract: From 2012 English universities and colleges will be operating in a more demanding market environment. There will be competition on tuition fees for undergraduate (Baccalaureate) programs for the first time. New private, including “for profitâ€, providers will be entering the market. There will be much more information about what institutions will be offering to existing and potential students. The Government believes that this will raise quality as well as providing a sustainable basis for the future. However there is little evidence to support these beliefs and considerable grounds for supposing that these policies will create a more stratified, and potentially more wasteful, system.
    Keywords: Education
    Date: 2011–05–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cdl:cshedu:2127962&r=lab
  40. By: Stephan Klasen (Georg-August-University Göttingen); Simon Lange (Georg-August-University Göttingen)
    Abstract: Most numerical targets within the framework of the Millennium Development Goals (MDGs) are overly ambitious for the poorest countries when interpreted as country-specic goals. As a consequence, the current system undermines accountability and ownership and jeopardizes the public support the MDGs have drawn in the past. This paper proposes an alternative approach to evaluating progress towards non-income MDGs that allows a sensible appraisal of countries' progress. We first estimate transition paths towards high levels of achievement for four MDG indicators (under-five mortality, primary completion, and gender equality in education). In line with previous empirical work, we find that the sigmoid-shaped transition path captures several features of past transition episodes. Accounting only for initial levels and time elapsed, our models explain up to 80 percent of the within-country variation in the data depending on the indicator considered. Estimated transition paths are then used to project progress towards low levels of under-five mortality since 1990. Comparing actual with projected progress allows us to identify over- and underachievers based on realistic expectations. For example, we find that while some countries in Sub-Sahara Africa have in fact shown considerable performance towards low levels of under-five mortality, the bulk of the the countries in that region is still lagging behind. Finally, we provide some preliminary regression results.
    Keywords: millennium development goals; human development; mortality transition; education transition
    Date: 2011–08–12
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:got:gotcrc:087&r=lab
  41. By: Jorge Soares (Department of Economics,University of Delaware)
    Abstract: I compare the welfare implications of implementing Bismarckian and Beveridgean social security systems. In an overlapping generations environment with intragenerational homogeneity, agents can be better off with a system with universal benefits than with a comparable system with earnings-dependent benefits because the latter generates a stronger decrease in net wages. Once I allow for intragenerational skill heterogeneity, agents are on average better off with the more redistributive universal benefits system. I then let agents vote for the replacement rates in a democratic process. In the absence of intragenerational heterogeneity, a larger social security system is implemented when benefits are earnings-dependent than when they are universal resulting in a larger decrease in net wages; this makes young agents worse o¤ with earnings-dependent benefits. In the presence of intragenerational skill heterogeneity, the reverse occurs and agents fare on average better in the long-run when benefits are earnings-dependent. However, because of its redistributional effects, agents born at the time of implementation are on average better o¤ with an universal benefits system.
    Keywords: social security, universal benefits, earnings-dependent benefits, Bismarckian social security system, Beveridgean social security system, voting, welfare.
    JEL: E62 H55
    Date: 2011
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:dlw:wpaper:11-14.&r=lab
  42. By: Marisa Coetzee
    Abstract: The paper estimates the impact of the South African Child Support Grant (CSG) on child health, nutrition and education. Data from the 2008 South African National Income Dynamics Study (NIDS) are used. Two non-experimental treatment evaluation techniques, both relying on propensity scores, are applied to six different outcome variables. Using propensity score matching with a binary outcome variable, no convincing evidence of improvements on any of the outcome variables is found. A second technique is therefore also applied, using a generalised form of the propensity scores. This follows the approach of Hirano and Imbens (2004) and Agüero et al. (2009). The generalised approach estimates a positive treatment effect for children’s height-for-age and progress through the school system. Although these estimates do provide some evidence of the positive effect of the Child Support Grant on the lives of children, the estimates are small and do not provide clear evidence that the transfers received by caregivers are spent mainly on improving the well-being of beneficiary children. Some potential and plausible explanations for this result are discussed in the paper. Nevertheless, the findings seem to suggest that some of the cash transferred through the Child Support Grant appears to be spent on improving the well-being of children.
    Keywords: Conditional cash transfer child health and nutrition continuous treatment estimator South Africa
    JEL: I38 H53 C21 D13
    Date: 2011
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:rza:wpaper:230&r=lab
  43. By: Hazan, Moshe
    Abstract: I argue that distinguishing between life expectancy at birth and life expectancy beyond the crucial early childhood years affects the relationship between life expectancy and schooling in a meaningful way. In particular, I show that while the change in life expectancy at birth between 1960 and 1990 is positively correlated with percentage change in schooling, the change in life expectancy at age 5 is, at best, uncorrelated with percentage change in schooling. This evidence weakens the quantitative importance of increasing life horizon beyond the early crucial childhood years for formal acquisition of human capital.
    Keywords: Human Capital; Life expectancy
    JEL: J24 O11
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cpr:ceprdp:8524&r=lab
  44. By: Jeffrey B. Liebman; Erzo F.P. Luttmer
    Abstract: This paper presents the results of a field experiment in which a sample of older workers was randomized between a treatment group that was given information about key Social Security provisions and a control group that was not. The experiment was designed to examine whether it is possible to affect individual behavior using a relatively inexpensive informational intervention about the provisions of a public program and to explore the mechanisms underlying the behavior change. We find that our relatively mild intervention (sending an informational brochure and an invitation to a web-tutorial) increased labor force participation one year later by 4 percentage points relative to the control group mean of 74 percent and that this effect is driven by a 7.2 percentage point increase among female subjects. The information intervention increased the perceived returns to working longer, especially among female respondents, which suggests that the behavioral response can be attributed at least in part to updated information about Social Security.
    JEL: C93 D83 H55 J26
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:17287&r=lab
  45. By: Jacques Forest; Marylène Gagné
    Abstract: Although compensation specialists generally argue for incentive systems that link rewards to performance, self-determination theory argues that such contingent rewards can have detrimental effects on autonomous motivation. The authors present a model of the motivational effects of compensation systems that attempts to reconcile the self-determination theory view and the literature on compensation. This model evaluates how compensation system characteristics, such as the amount and variability of pay, can influence the satisfaction of the needs for autonomy, competence, and relatedness, which in turn influence autonomous work motivation. <P>Si les spécialistes en rémunération sont généralement en faveur des systèmes de primes qui lient la récompense à la performance, la théorie de l’autodétermination, quant à elle, suggère que de telles récompenses contingentes peuvent nuire à la motivation autonome. Nous présentons un modèle des effets motivationnels engendrés par les systèmes de rémunération qui tente de faire concorder la théorie de l’autodétermination avec la documentation sur la rémunération. Ce modèle évalue de quelle façon les caractéristiques des systèmes de rémunération, tels les variations de la rémunération et son niveau, peuvent influer sur la satisfaction du besoin d’autonomie, la compétence et le rapprochement, lesquels peuvent, à leur tour, marquer la motivation autonome au travail.
    Keywords: self-determination theory, compensation, rewards, incentives, organizational justice., théorie de l’autodétermination, compensation, récompenses, mesures incitatives, justice organisationnelle.
    Date: 2011–08–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cir:cirwor:2011s-54&r=lab
  46. By: C. Judson King
    Abstract: Disciplines codify related knowledge and have developed powerful approaches that enable both solutions to a wide variety of problems and efficient further extension of knowledge. Individual disciplines have translated into individual departments within universities. Academic departments tend to turn inward, deepening the knowledge within the discipline. Because of this inwardness, the differing methodological approaches among disciplines, and the reward systems within disciplines and universities, it is difficult for faculty to reach outside their disciplines and departments, so as to share knowledge and/or mine knowledge at the intersections of disciplines. However, world needs and opportunities are increasingly complex and require integrated, in-depth contributions from multiple disciplines for progress. Means for universities to encourage and facilitate multidisciplinary activities include organizational structure, incentive budgeting, and leadership and resources that enable directors of multidisciplinary units to negotiate effectively with academic department chairs. Major competitive initiatives involving large resources have proven particularly effective. New universities have opportunities for multidisciplinary research and teaching that would be much more difficult within existing universities. Today’s university graduates must be able to work effectively with persons from other disciplines and understand enough of the basic vocabulary and methodologies of other disciplines to enable that collaboration. A liberal undergraduate education addresses those needs, where the definition of “liberal†encompasses courses reflecting many different disciplines, including the natural sciences and even some engineering. Professions are properly placed at the graduate level, built upon a foundational liberal education. Engineering should join the other professions by changing to that structure.
    Keywords: Education
    Date: 2010–09–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cdl:cshedu:2127923&r=lab
  47. By: Rao, Bhaskara; Shankar, Sriram
    Abstract: This paper estimates with the least trimmed least squares (LTS) a specification suitable to estimate the permanent growth effects of human capital, using educational attainment (H) as a proxy. Our results show that H has significant permanent growth effects but these are much smaller than in Temple (1999).
    Keywords: Least Trimmed Squares; Human capital; Educational attainment; Permanent growth effects
    JEL: O15 O40
    Date: 2011–08–12
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:32775&r=lab
  48. By: Martinho, Vítor João Pereira Domingues
    Abstract: In this work we pretend to present a project of research about the identification of the determinants that affect the mobility of labor. The empirical part of the work will be performed for the NUTS II of Portugal, from 1996 to 2002. As main conclusion it can be said which is confirmed the existence of some labor mobility in Portugal and that regional mobility is mainly influenced positively by the output growth and negatively by the unemployment rates and by the weight of the agricultural sector. This study analyses, also, through cross-section estimation methods, the influence of spatial effects and human capital in the conditional productivity convergence in the economic sectors of NUTs III of mainland Portugal between 1995 and 2002.
    Keywords: net migration; convergence; panel and cross-section estimations; Portuguese regions
    JEL: O18 O47 C23 R11 C21 R23
    Date: 2011
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:32801&r=lab
  49. By: Wang, Chen; Caminada, Koen
    Abstract: The aim of this paper is to offer detailed information of fiscal redistribution in 36 countries, employing data that have been computed from the Luxembourg Income Study’s micro-level database. LIS data are detailed enough to allow us to measure both overall redistribution, and the partial effects of redistribution by several taxes or transfers. We elaborate on the work of Jesuit and Mahler (2004) and Mahler and Jesuit (2006), and we refine, update and extent their Fiscal Redistribution approach. LIS data allow us to decompose the trajectory of the Gini coefficient from primary to disposable income inequality in several parts: we will distinguish 11 different benefits and several income taxes and social contributions in our empirical investigation across countries. First, we use LIS data to analyze income inequality and the redistributive effect of social transfers across countries in a descriptive way. Then we proceed with a simulation approach for 36 countries for which we decompose income inequality through several taxes and transfers. We analyze the redistributive effect of several social programs, like unemployment benefits or pensions and income taxes. We develop a budget incidence simulation model to investigate to what extent several social transfers contribute to the overall redistribution in modern welfare states under a strong assumption that the absence of social transfers and taxes would not change individual behavior and labor supply. Among all countries listed in this paper, Denmark and Sweden have the smallest income disparity, while Peru and Colombia have the largest. Nordic countries show the most equally distributed disposable incomes and primary incomes, comparing to the countries in other types of welfare states. On average, large primary income disparity exists in Anglo-Saxon countries. Generally speaking, European countries achieve lower levels of income inequality than other countries. With respect to the redistributive effect, our budget incidence analysis indicates that the pattern is diverse across countries. The largest redistribution is found for Belgium, while Colombia and Peru show rather limited overall redistributive effects. On average, transfers reduce income inequality by over 85 percent, while taxes account for only 15 percent of total redistribution. Among all welfare states, Continental European countries (Belgium, France, Germany, and Luxembourg) achieve the highest level of the reduction of initial income inequality. As far as social programs is concerned, in most countries two dominant income components account for above 50 percent of total reduction in income inequality: the public old age pensions and the survivors scheme, and the income taxes. For example, in Southern European Countries the public old age benefits account for over 80 percent of total redistribution, while these figures are much lower for Anglo-Saxon Countries (20-34%), for Nordic Countries (31-48%), for Continental European Countries (47-57%), and for Central Eastern European Countries (54-70%). In Anglo-Saxon Countries income taxes play a major role (above 30%) compare to other countries (with the exception the United kingdom). Also the redistributive effect of social assistance and child and family benefits in the Anglo-Saxon Countries are relatively high in a comparative setting (9-28%). In Nordic Countries also a variety of other social programs contribute to the reduction of inequality, especially the disability scheme (9-15%). Remarkably, across countries all other social benefit programs seem to have rather limited redistributive effects, although the unemployment compensation benefits do have some effect too.
    Keywords: welfare states, social income transfers, inequality, Gini coefficient, LIS
    JEL: H55 H53 I32
    Date: 2011–08–04
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:32821&r=lab
  50. By: Liam Delaney (Stirling University, UCD Geary Institute, University College Dublin); Michael Egan (UCD Geary Institute); Nicola O'Connell (UCD Geary Institute)
    Abstract: This paper reports on the results of 13 semi-structured focus groups carried out with unemployed respondents across Ireland in 2010. The purpose of the research is to examine the subjective experience of unemployment across a wide range of dimensions. 15 overarching themes emerged from a detailed thematic analysis of the texts of the interviews. The themes highlight a wide range of aversive psychological states associated with unemployment. The themes examine: perceptions of the economic boom; reactions to the recession; attitudes toward media coverage; gender differences in experiences of unemployment; financial worries relating to unemployment; perceptions of the position of young people; uncertainty about the future; lack of structure and routine associated with unemployment; health issues associated with unemployment; identity challenges; the social context of unemployment; issues surrounding reentering employment; attitudes toward social protection payments; social comparison effect and perceptions of training services. This paper concludes with a brief discussion of the psychological impact of unemployment.
    Date: 2011–08–18
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ucd:wpaper:201116&r=lab
  51. By: Yamamura, Eiji; Andrés, Antonio
    Abstract: Using individual-level data from China, Korea, and Japan for 2006, this research examines how the age of children of the relationship influences marital satisfaction for males and females in East Asian countries. Our results show that the marital satisfaction of males is barely affected by a child of the relationship, whereas the marital satisfaction of females with a young child is lower than that of females who do not have a child. This result holds for countries of different development stages. There is also a gender differential regarding the effect of young children on marital satisfaction. Furthermore, the more developed the country, the greater this difference becomes.
    Keywords: Marital satisfaction; child; East Asian countries; probit
    JEL: J13 D19 J16
    Date: 2011–06–25
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:32756&r=lab
  52. By: Francisco López Segrera
    Abstract: Universities in Latin America and in the Caribbean (LAC), and throughout the world, are facing one of the most challenging eras in their history. Globalization presents many important opportunities for higher education, but also poses serious problems and raises questions about how best to serve the common good. The traditional values of universities are still valid (autonomy, academic freedom, research, students´ work, assessment), but they should be viewed within the context of new global norms. Until the decade of the 80s, public HE with institutional and academic autonomy, had predominance in the region over the private education. At the end of the 80s and beginnings of the 90s, globalization meant neoliberal strategies. This implied replacing the typical policies of the “Welfare Stateâ€, for others of reducing funds to public services and privatization of them. These market strategies had an impact in the increasing privatization of HE and in the deterioration of public universities, due to the lack of appropriate financing among other factors. In spite of this, during the 90s HE grew a great deal. HE reforms in LAC in the last two decades, have been oriented towards the satisfaction of an increasing demand according to World Bank policies and in much lesser degree to the policies recommended by UNESCO in the WCHE (1998). Because of it, these transformations are mainly counter-reforms and not the needed reform of the national public university. This essay provides an outline of the major challenges facing universities throughout the world, This then give context to a discussion on current policy reforms and the future of higher education in Latin and Caribbean nations where enrollment and program growth is robust. This includes: cooperation in networks as an alternative to competition; open content and open knowledge versus privatization and marketing visions of new providers of for-profit higher education; new participative instruments of management, evaluation and accreditation; research aimed at global and local needs simultaneously; a sustainable development vision in order to achieve the millennium goals should be incorporated to curriculum as well as studies on multiculturalism and diversity.
    Keywords: Education
    Date: 2010–09–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cdl:cshedu:2127925&r=lab
  53. By: Silva, Leonardo Fonseca da; Ferreira, Pedro Cavalcanti
    Abstract: We investigate the role of sectorial differences in labor productivity and the process of structural transformation (reallocation of labor across sectors) in accounting for the time path of aggregate productivity across six Latin American countries (Brazil, Chile, Argentina, Colombia, Mexico and Venezuela) from 1950 to 2003. We used a general equilibrium model with three sectors (agriculture, industry and services) calibrated to those six economies. The model is used to compare the trajectory of productivity in each sector of activity with that of the United States and it impact on aggregate productivity.While in Brazil and Argentina, the Service Sector was responsible for reversing the process of catch up in productivity that occurred until the 1980s, in others, like Colombia, Mexico and Venezuela, low productivity growth of the three sectors explain their poor performance.
    Date: 2011–08–12
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:fgv:epgewp:724&r=lab
  54. By: John Aubrey Douglass, Richard Edelstein and Cecile Hoareau
    Abstract: During the 2009-10 academic year international students generated more than $18.8 billion in net income into the US economy. California alone had nearly 100,000 international students with an economic impact of nearly $3.0 billion. In this paper, we outline a strategy for the San Francisco/Bay Area to double the number of international students enrolled in local colleges and universities in ten years or less, generating a total direct economic impact of an additional $1 billion a year into the regional economy. The US retains a huge market advantage for attracting foreign students. Within the US, the San Francisco/Bay Area is particularly attractive and could prevail as an extraordinary global talent magnet, if only policymakers and higher education leaders better understood this and formulated strategies to tap the global demand for higher education. Ultimately, all globalism is local. We propose that the San Francisco/Bay Area, a region with a group of stellar universities and colleges, should re-imagine itself as a Global Higher Education Hub to meet national and regional economic needs, as well as the thirst of a growing world population for high-quality tertiary education. Other parts of the world have already developed their version of the higher education hub idea. The major difference in our proposed Californian version is that foreign competitors seek to attract foreign universities to help build enrollment and program capacity at home, and are funded almost solely by significant government subsidies. Our model builds capacity, but is focused on attracting the world’s talent and generating additional income to existing public and private colleges and universities. Doubling international enrollment from 30,000 to 60,000 students in ten years or less will require expanding regional enrollment capacity as part of a strategy to ensure access to native students, and as part of a scheme to attract a new generation of faculty and researchers to the Bay Area and California. International students would need to pay higher then the full cost of their education, helping to subsidize domestic students and college and university programs. The result would be a San Francisco/Bay Area Global Higher Education Hub – a self-reinforcing knowledge ecosystem that is internationally attractive, socially beneficial, and economically viable. We offer a path for analyzing the feasibility of this Global Higher Education Hub, including the steps necessary to engage the private sector and local government to help create enrollment capacity and academic programs, a discussion of a financial model, possible marketing strategies, and for developing shared facilities and services. This initiative will require most Bay Area colleges and universities, including UC Berkeley and Stanford University, to collaborate. By providing a leadership role, Berkeley and Stanford would help brand the hub idea internationally, provide leadership in shaping direct and indirect economic returns of the SF/Bay area higher education hub, while also gaining from the increased international attractiveness of the region and the use of shared facilities. It is about the money. But it is also about establishing closer ties with the regional universities and colleges, business interests and local governments, enhancing the quality and reputation of our universities and colleges, building enrollment capacity for native students, integrating international perspectives into the activities and learning of students and faculty, and broadening the opportunity for international collaborations. It is about solidifying the Bay Area as a global talent magnet, one that is even more culturally diverse, even more innovative, and that continues to attract talent from throughout the world. We conclude the paper by suggesting that a regionally based knowledge hub would also be a viable strategy for a select group of other urban areas of the US.
    Keywords: Education
    Date: 2011–05–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cdl:cshedu:2127968&r=lab
  55. By: Roel van Elk
    Abstract: <p>Recently, there has been considerable debate about a reform of the Dutch system of student support, in which grants will be (partly) replaced by loans. </p><p>The discussion focuses on the effects on student enrollment decisions. Surprisingly, no study has yet analysed the effect of receiving a grant on parental contribution. Parents may decrease their contribution when their child receives a grant, in which case subsidies meant for the students unintentionally end up with the parents. Understanding the corresponding parental behaviour will contribute to a more in-depth discussion on the financial aid system.</p><p>This paper focuses on the effect of the supplementary grant on the parental contribution in the Netherlands. The supplementary grant is meant to support students from disadvantaged families. Parents from students with the supplementary grant have less disposable income, which probably implies a lower contribution. Our identification strategy separates this income effect from the effect due to the payments of the supplementary grant. The results suggest substantial substitution. Each additional euro spent on supplementary grant reduces the parental contribution with approximately 20-60 cents. A broad range of sensitivity analyses support our main estimation results. Nevertheless, some caution in interpreting the results is needed because of data limitations.</p>
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cpb:discus:187&r=lab
  56. By: Siebert, W. Stanley (University of Birmingham); Peng, Fei (University of Birmingham); Maimaiti, Yasheng (University of Birmingham)
    Abstract: This paper analyses HRM practices of family-run workplaces using the 2004 WERS. Family-ownership and management within workplaces in the corporate sector is our focus. This family-run group represents nationally about 26% of workplaces and 14% of employment. We find that employees in this group have stronger feelings of job security and loyalty, which we relate to family companies' HRM practices such as stronger support for long-term employment – an "inclusivity" linked to long-term orientation. We also find that family-owned and managed workplaces have better financial and quality performance measures than non-family, to which family-related HRM practices contribute.
    Keywords: job security, loyalty, family business, HRM practices, financial performance
    JEL: J01 L26 M54
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp5899&r=lab
  57. By: Jasso, Guillermina (New York University)
    Abstract: Migration and stratification are increasingly intertwined. One day soon it will be impossible to understand one without the other. Both focus on life chances. Stratification is about differential life chances – who gets what and why – and migration is about improving life chances – getting more of the good things of life. To examine the interconnections of migration and stratification, we address a mix of old and new questions, carrying out analyses newly enabled by a unique new data set on recent legal immigrants to the United States (the New Immigrant Survey). We look at immigrant processing and lost documents, depression due to the visa process, presentation of self, the race-ethnic composition of an immigrant cohort (made possible by the data for the first time since 1961), black immigration from Africa and the Americas, skin-color diversity among couples formed by U.S. citizen sponsors and immigrant spouses, and English fluency among children age 8-12 and their immigrant parents. We find, inter alia, that children of previously illegal parents are especially more likely to be fluent in English, that native-born U.S. citizen women tend to marry darker, that immigrant applicants who go through the visa process while already in the United States are more likely to have their documents lost and to suffer visa depression, and that immigration, by introducing accomplished black immigrants from Africa (notably via the visa lottery), threatens to overturn racial and skin color associations with skill. Our analyses show the mutual embeddedness of migration and stratification in the unfolding of the immigrants' and their children's life chances and the impacts on the stratification structure of the United States.
    Keywords: immigration, immigrant visas, social stratification, gender, race, Hispanic origin, skin color, presentation of self, visa depression, illegal experience, English fluency, spouse selection, children of immigrants, nativity premium, New Immigrant Survey
    JEL: F22 J15 J16 J24 K42
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp5904&r=lab
  58. By: Simon Ville (University of Wollongong); Peter Siminski (University of Wollongong)
    Abstract: Australia’s commitment to the Vietnam War drew on the selective conscription of additional manpower through 16 biannual ballots. 20-year-old men were liable to serve if their date of birth was drawn out. The random nature of the ballot was seen as an equitable method of selection for a system of labour coercion that was potentially life-threatening. We investigate the various stages of conscription of these ‘national servicemen’ to undertake service in Vietnam throughout the war and evaluate the extent to which the processes provided for fair and equitable selection. Comparisons are drawn with a similar process of Vietnam-War era conscription in the United States.
    Keywords: Australia; conscription; ballot; Vietnam War
    JEL: J45 N37 N47 H56
    Date: 2011
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:uow:depec1:wp11-05&r=lab
  59. By: Fry, J. M.; Masood, Omar
    Abstract: Motivated by an on-going debate in economic history we develop a simple method to quantify the impact of economic revolutions upon a novel historical data set listing the wages of building craftsmen and labourers in Southeast Europe. Structural breaks are found in the data and signify the effects of economic revolutions. With a small number of localised exceptions economic revolutions, caused by technological and administrative progress, lead to a decrease in the long-term level of wage volatility and overall results suggest close analogies between biological and economic evolution. The Commercial Revolution (mid 16th-early 18th centuries) acts as an important pre-requisite for the later Industrial Revolution (mid 18th-19th centuries). The Price Revolution (15th-16th centuries) results in some short-term increases in wage volatility.
    Keywords: Historical Economics; Economic Revolutions; Economic Evolution; European Wages
    JEL: N01 N00 G00
    Date: 2011–08–15
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:32812&r=lab
  60. By: Katharine Lyall
    Abstract: The business models under which most public universities in the U.S. operate have become unsustainable. They were put in place when state economies were stronger and there were fewer programs making competing claims on state funds. The current Great Recession has made things worse, but the unsustainability of current business models derives from longer-term trends that will prevent state investment in higher education from rebounding to prior levels. States and universities are making both incremental and structural changes in response. Incremental changes work within existing financial and governance parameters to effect cost savings and/or to extend services; they stretch the use of existing or shrinking resources. Structural reforms change financial and/or governance parameters to create different incentives, which focus on performance, outcomes, and stabilizing capacity. A number of these new models are summarized including: “charter†and “public authority†models, the Virginia tiered system model, the Oregon public endowment model, and the UK income-contingent model. Current conditions create both a challenge and an opportunity for statewide higher education systems to re-define their missions and priorities to sustain their public universities for the future. Whether changes are made by drift or by design will determine how well public universities can contribute to the growth of the country in future decades.
    Keywords: Education
    Date: 2011–06–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cdl:cshedu:2127970&r=lab
  61. By: López Real, Joel
    Abstract: While the immigration policy in the United States is mainly oriented to family reunification, in Australia, Canada and the United Kingdom. it is a points-based immigration system which main objective is to attract high skilled immigrants. This paper compares both immigration policies through the transition for the United States and Mexico. I find that: (i) the point system increases the average years of the immigrants by 3.5 years; (ii) the Mexican immigrants suffer a 10% reduction in their effective hours of labor when they move to the United States; (iii) migration reduces inequality, more significantly if the immigration policy is the point system and increases output per capita differences between both countries; (iv) the offspring of the immigrants invest more in human capital than the United States natives; (v) the earnings ratio immigrants to the United States natives is lower under the quota system than under the point system but along the transition it reverses converging at the steady state. --
    Keywords: Migration,self-selection,human capital,immigration policies
    JEL: E20 F22 J61 O11
    Date: 2011
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:zbw:ifwedp:201127&r=lab
  62. By: Besley, Timothy J.; Ghatak, Maitreesh
    Abstract: We explore the consequence for taxation and regulation of bonus pay when investors are protected by taxpayers from downside risk. The paper develops a model where workers in financial sector firms make decisions about effort and risk-taking which are influenced by the structure of bonus pay. Bailouts lead to too little effort, too much risk taking and increase inequality. We show that the optimal structure of bonuses can be implemented by a combination of a regulation on the structure of bonuses and a tax on their level.
    Keywords: bonus; incentives; taxation
    JEL: D53 D86 H21
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cpr:ceprdp:8532&r=lab
  63. By: Cécile Hoareau
    Abstract: The French Government has had a paradoxical relationship with globalization. Globalization is perceived as both a threat to react against and a cradle for new policy ideas. French policymakers have a love-hate relationship with the European higher education reforms that started in the 1990s, a mixed sentiment that French singer Serge Gainsbourg spoke of in his popular song, ‘Je t’aime moi non plus’. At the outset, most of higher education reforms, such as the Bologna declaration, were framed as a way to build Europe and fight against international competition. Yet, the mode of governance of these reforms mirrored the one recommended by international organizations and led to the precise outcome criticized in globalization, i.e. greater competition. This paper explores the relationship between international, European and domestic discourses and modes of governance. It uses insights from the literature on policy transfer to investigate such relationship and questions the sustainability of such ambivalent discourse. The French government should concentrate on the policy it started developing from 2007 consisting in opening French higher education to globalization. Such global openness requires a change in the academic culture that could be triggered by a reform of academic training.
    Keywords: Education
    Date: 2011–01–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cdl:cshedu:2127951&r=lab
  64. By: Grönqvist, Hans (Swedish Institute for Social Research, Stockholm University); Niknami, Susan (Swedish Institute for Social Research, Stockholm University)
    Abstract: In February 2000, the Swedish state monopoly alcohol retail company launched a large scale experiment in which all stores in selected counties were allowed to keep open on Saturdays. We assess the effects on crime of this expansion in access to alcohol. To isolate the impact of the experiment from other factors, we compare conviction rates in age cohorts above and below the national drinking age restriction in counties where the experiment had been implemented, and contrast these differences to those in counties that still prohibited weekend alcohol commerce. Our analysis relies on extensive individual conviction data that have been merged to population registers. After demonstrating that Saturday opening of alcohol shops significantly raised alcohol sales, we show that it also increased crime. The increase is confined to crimes committed on Saturdays and is driven by illegal activity among individuals with low ability and among persons with fathers that have completed at least some secondary education. Although the increases in crime and alcohol sales were slightly higher during the initial phase of the experiment, our evidence suggests that both effects persist over time. Our analysis reveals that the social costs linked to the experiment exceed the monetary benefits.
    Keywords: Delinquency; Alcohol laws; Substance use
    JEL: K42
    Date: 2011–08–02
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hhs:sofiwp:2011_009&r=lab
  65. By: Gregg Thomson
    Abstract: This paper reviews the new directions in institutional research on undergraduate racial/ethnic and socioeconomic diversity at the University of California, Berkeley. The use of SERU/UCUES and other web-based census surveys has made possible more detailed and extensive analysis of student diversity. Included is research on an expanded number of racial/ethnic groups and on multiracial students, the significance of the African American experience, implications of the new IPEDS racial/ethnic reporting requirements, and a closer examination of Pell Grant and first-generation college students. UCUES survey results are used to development a more comprehensive parental education and immigrant generation diversity (EID) typology that is then used to examine the interrelationships among student demographics and various facets of the undergraduate academic experience. Finally, an analysis of student accounts of the experience of diversity at Berkeley provides an example of how web-based census surveys afford new opportunities for cost-effective qualitative diversity research.
    Keywords: Education
    Date: 2011–05–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cdl:cshedu:2127964&r=lab
  66. By: Viitanen, Tarja (University of Otago)
    Abstract: This paper examines the effect of parental divorce during childhood on generalized trust later on in life using Australian HILDA panel data. The dependent variable is composed of answers to the statement: “Generally speaking, most people can be trusted”. The main explanatory variables include the occurrence of parental divorce for the whole sample and the age at which parents divorced for the sub-sample. The analysis is conducted using random effects ordered probit, correlated random effects ordered probit and instrumental variables ordered probit models. The results indicate that the level of generalized trust is significantly affected by parental divorce for both men and women. This main result is very robust to alternative specifications. Furthermore, there is a marginally significant effect on the expressed level of generalized trust due to age at which parents divorced for women, but not men.
    Keywords: parental divorce, generalized trust, HILDA, random effects ordered probit, instrumental variables ordered probit
    JEL: J12 J13 H8 Z13
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp5898&r=lab

This nep-lab issue is ©2011 by Stephanie Lluis. It is provided as is without any express or implied warranty. It may be freely redistributed in whole or in part for any purpose. If distributed in part, please include this notice.
General information on the NEP project can be found at http://nep.repec.org. For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese at <director@nep.repec.org>. Put “NEP” in the subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.