|
on Intellectual Property Rights |
By: | Gaétan de Rassenfosse (Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research, The University of Melbourne; Intellectual Property Research Institute of Australia, The University of Melbourne); Anja Schoen (Technische Universität München); Annelies Wastyn (Department of Managerial Economics, Strategy and Innovation, KU Leuven) |
Abstract: | The study of the innovative output of organizations often relies on a count of patents filed at one single office of reference such as the European Patent Office (EPO). Yet, not all organizations file their patents at the EPO, raising the specter of a selection bias. Using novel datasets of the whole population of patents by Belgian firms and German universities, we show that the single-office count results in a selection bias that affects econometric estimates of invention production functions. We propose a methodology to evaluate whether estimates that rely on the single-office count are affected by a selection bias. |
Keywords: | Knowledge production function, patent count, R&D, selection bias |
JEL: | O31 C18 C52 C81 |
Date: | 2013–03 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iae:iaewps:wp2013n08&r=ipr |
By: | Cozza, Claudio; Schettino, Francesco |
Abstract: | The aim of this paper is to study empirically the patenting propensity at the European regional level. To do that we use the OECD-REGPAT dataset, that includes patent applications made by European inventors and applicants to EPO in the time-span 1978-2011. Explanatory variables on R&D and human capital are extracted from EUROSTAT and OECD databases. In order to reduce biases we use patent applications by region of the inventor, as its linkage to the territory is stronger than using the region of the applicant. Analyzing the data, we sketch out the existence of a deep uneven distribution both in patent applications and R&D expenditure. Richer regions in terms of GDP – generally those of central-western Europe – show higher level of both private and public R&D expenditure as well as a consistent share of the whole European patent applications in last decades. As a consequence, eastern (and to a minor extent southern) European regions report harmful outcomes in terms of both variables. Thus, following the approach of Cincera (1997, 2005) we explain the determinants of patenting propensity using a regional panel data. Our main results substantially confirm the key role of R&D expenditure on patenting activity: mainly the business-enterprises component, but also the government sector one. Moreover, human capital variables – such as the share of human resources employed in high tech industries, and the number of highly qualified workers in science and technology occupations – show a positive relationship with patenting propensity. On the other side, average enterprise size seems not to play a determinant role on patent applications. |
Keywords: | Patents, Intellectual Property Rights, Innovation, EPO, R&D |
JEL: | K29 O34 O4 |
Date: | 2013–03–01 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:45084&r=ipr |
By: | Gaétan de Rassenfosse (Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research, The University of Melbourne; Intellectual Property Research Institute of Australia, The University of Melbourne) |
Abstract: | This paper presents evidence that firms face a trade-off between the quantity and quality of their research output. The econometric analysis uses survey data on patent applicants at the European Patent Office and addresses the identification problem caused by differences in firms’ propensity to patent. The existence of a trade-off emphasizes the need to take the quality of research output into account when assessing research productivity. It also raises questions about the optimal quantity–quality mix that firms should target. |
Keywords: | Innovation performance, invention quality, invention quantity, patent explosion, propensity to patent, research productivity |
JEL: | D83 L25 O31 O33 |
Date: | 2013–02 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iae:iaewps:wp2013n06&r=ipr |
By: | Tetsugen Haruyama (Graduate School of Economics, Kobe University) |
Date: | 2013–03 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:koe:wpaper:1305&r=ipr |
By: | Paul H. Jensen (Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research, The University of Melbourne; Intellectual Property Research Institute of Australia, The University of Melbourne); Alfons Palangkaraya (Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research, The University of Melbourne; Intellectual Property Research Institute of Australia, The University of Melbourne); Elizabeth Webster (Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research, The University of Melbourne; Intellectual Property Research Institute of Australia, The University of Melbourne) |
Abstract: | Conditional on the decision to enter the market for immature technology, we test for the effects that trust – as proxied by the context in which the negotiating parties met – has on the likelihood that these negotiations are successful. Using a randomised dataset of 860 university-firm and firm-firm technology transactions, we find that the depth of prior relationship and circumstantial knowledge about each other matters, and matters a lot. Parties who knew each other from a previous business are 28.2 percentage points more likely to conclude a transaction compared with cold-callers. Meeting via an industry network offers an intermediate advantage but meeting via a third party or at a conference only offers a modest advantage over cold calling. |
Keywords: | Markets for technology, R&D, invention, patent |
JEL: | O31 O34 |
Date: | 2013–02 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iae:iaewps:wp2013n03&r=ipr |
By: | Chen, Hung-Ju |
Abstract: | This study investigates the effects of stronger intellectual property rights (IPR) protection in the South on innovation, skills choice, wage inequality and patterns of production based on a North-South general-equilibrium model with foreign direct investment (FDI) and international outsourcing. We find that stronger IPR protection in the South raises the extent of outsourcing and reduces the extent of FDI. This raises the proportion of Southerners being unskilled and mitigates wage inequality in the South. In the North, stronger Southern IPR protection raises the proportion of Northerners being skilled and wage inequality. The effects of international specialization, R&D cost and Northern population are also examined. |
Keywords: | FDI; Outsourcing; Quality ladder; Skill; Wage inequality. |
JEL: | F12 F23 O31 |
Date: | 2013–03–14 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:45035&r=ipr |
By: | Nour, Samia Satti Osman Mohamed (Faculty of Economic and Social Studies, Khartoum University, and UNU-MERIT/MGSoG) |
Abstract: | This paper explains the importance of IPRs and examines the factors hindering and those contributing toward enhancing IPRs in Sudan. We find that the inadequacy of IPRs protection in Sudan is attributed to low integration in the international institutions, lack of legal issues, lack of government concern, lack of private sector concern, weak institutions setting, lack of public awareness, lack of resources, weak culture for IPRs, lack of cooperation between universities and industry and lack of coordination. The inadequate IPRs protection in Sudan leads to poor national system of innovation, hindering FDI and hindering transfer of technology. The factors contributing toward enhancing IPRs in Sudan include promotion of adequate IPRs legislations and enforcement; planning, commitment to international IPRs agreements; finance, investment and resources; social partnership to encourage IPRs protection, government concern, private sector concern, public awareness, cooperation between universities and industry, institutions setting, coordination and culture for IPRs protection. |
Keywords: | IPRs, economic importance, economic impacts, Sudan, Africa |
JEL: | O30 O34 |
Date: | 2013 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:dgr:unumer:2013014&r=ipr |
By: | Burak Dindaroglu (Department of Economics, Izmir University of Economics) |
Abstract: | I study the effects of basic and applied innovation on a firm's market value and total factor productivity for a panel of U.S. manufacturing firms. Basicness of innovation is measured by the index of generality proposed by Trajtenberg, Henderson and Jaffe (1997), and basic and applied innovation stocks are proxied by the stocks of patents that score at the relevant tails of the generality distribution. I find that the market valuation and productivity effects of basic and applied innovation are drastically different. Market value is positively associated with a firm's applied innovation stock, but it exhibits no association with its basic innovation stock. On the other hand, patents at the higher (resp. lower) quartiles of the generality distribution are positively (resp. negatively) associated with total factor productivity and productivity growth. Therefore, complementing previous studies on basic research, I find that the basicness of innovation is associated with a productivity premium. |
Keywords: | Basic innovation; Applied innovation; Patents; Citations; Generality; Market value; Tobin's q; Productivity. |
JEL: | O31 O33 L60 |
Date: | 2013–03 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:izm:wpaper:1301&r=ipr |
By: | Jeffrey J. Schott (Peterson Institute for International Economics); Cathleen Cimino (Peterson Institute for International Economics) |
Abstract: | A comprehensive Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP) has important implications for both US-EU bilateral trade and the world trading system. If successful, it could strengthen transatlantic economic relations while also spurring trade reforms that could reinvigorate flagging multilateral trade negotiations. Both sides want the TTIP to be a big deal covering all major components of the commercial relationship. They can achieve the pact's ambitious agenda by (1) broadly aligning their respective trade pacts with South Korea and (2) deepening market access commitments covering both tariff and nontariff barriers to trade in goods, agriculture, and services. KORUS and KOREU FTA precedents are instructive but will need to be supplemented or adjusted in three areas if the TTIP is to succeed: intellectual property issues, sanitary and phytosanitary measures, and the environment. In several other areas KORUS-KOREU differences should be easier to bridge, including services, investment, government procurement, and competition policy. |
Date: | 2013–03 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iie:pbrief:pb13-8&r=ipr |