nep-ino New Economics Papers
on Innovation
Issue of 2015‒03‒13
fifteen papers chosen by
Steffen Lippert
University of Auckland

  1. R&D Migration: a cross-national analysis By Aldieri, Luigi; Vinci, Concetto Paolo
  2. Strategic Conflicts on the Horizon: R&D Incentives for Environmental Technologies By Heyen, Daniel
  3. How does firms' perceived competition affect technological innovation in Luxembourg? By Raymond W.; Plotnikova T.
  4. Venture Capital and Knowledge Transfer By Dessi, Roberta; Yin, Nina
  5. Innovation, R&D spillovers, and the variety and concentration of the local production structure By Leppälä, Samuli
  6. The Limits of Lending : Banks and Technology Adoption Across Russia By Bircan, Cagatay; de Haas, R.
  7. Innovation dynamics and productivity : evidence for Latin America By Crespi G.A.; Tacsir E.; Vargas F.
  8. Sources of biopharmaceutical innovation: An assessment of intellectual property By Michael S. Kinch; Julio Raffo
  9. Regional heterogeneity and interregional research spillovers in European innovation: modeling and policy implications By Gianni Guastella; Frank van Oort
  10. International Knowledge Spillovers: The Benefits from Employing Immigrants By Jürgen Bitzer; Erkan Gören; Sanne Hiller
  11. Boosting Productivity in Russia: Skills, Education and Innovation By Lilas Demmou; Andreas Wörgötter
  12. The roles of import competition and export opportunities for technical change By Claudia Steinwender
  13. Liquidity and Firm Response to Fiscal Stimulus By Antonio Acconcia; Claudia Cantabene
  14. The First Cut is the Deepest: Repeated Interactions of Coauthorship and Academic Productivity in Nobel Laureate Teams By Ho Fai Chan; Ali Sina Onder; Benno Torgler
  15. 2013 EU Industrial R&D Investment Scoreboard By Hector Hernandez; Alexander Tuebke; Fernando Hervas; Antonio Vezzani; Sara Amoroso

  1. By: Aldieri, Luigi; Vinci, Concetto Paolo
    Abstract: This study contributes to existing literature on firms’ innovative activity examining the influence of both internal firms’ physical and R&D capital, and external national and international knowledge spillovers. The paper presents a cross national analysis of United States, Japan and Europe based upon a new dataset composed of 879 worldwide R&D-intensive manufacturing firms. The empirical results suggest that the effect of R&D capital stock on firms’ innovation output is always positive. The effects of international R&D spillovers are positive in Japan and USA and negative in European economic area, while the national R&D spillovers has the opposite impact
    Keywords: R&D spillovers; Innovation; Cross-national analysis
    JEL: C23 O33 O4
    Date: 2015–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:62541&r=ino
  2. By: Heyen, Daniel
    Abstract: Technological innovation is a key strategy for tackling environmental problems. The required R&D expenditures however are substantial and fall on self-interested countries. Thus, the prospects of successful innovation critically depend on innovation incentives. This paper focuses on a specific mechanism for strategic distortions in this R&D game. In this mechanism, the outlook of future conflicts surrounding technology deployment directly impacts on the willingness to undertake R&D. Apart from free-riding, a different deployment conflict with distortive effects on innovation may occur: Low deployment costs and heterogeneous preferences might give rise to 'free-driving'. In this recently considered possibility (Weitzman 2012), the country with the highest preference for technology deployment, the free-driver, may dominate the deployment outcome to the detriment of others. The present paper develops a simple two stage model for analyzing how technology deployment conflicts, free-riding and free-driving, shape R&D incentives of two asymmetric countries. The framework gives rise to rich findings, underpinning the narrative that future deployment conflicts pull forward to the R&D stage. While the outlook of free-riding unambiguously weakens innovation incentives, the findings for free-driving are more complex, including the possibility of super-optimal R&D and incentives for counter-R&D.
    Date: 2015–03–02
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:awi:wpaper:0584&r=ino
  3. By: Raymond W.; Plotnikova T. (UNU-MERIT)
    Abstract: This paper revisits the competition-innovation relationship using an unbalanced panel of enterprise data stemming from four waves of the Luxembourgish innovation survey for the period 2002-2010. We estimate by full-information maximum likelihood a nonlinear dynamic simultaneous-equations model with pseudo-fixed effects using four measures of perceived competition and three indicators of innovation and find that firms whose main market is characterised by rapid obsolescence of products are more likely to spend on innovation and to introduce product or process innovations. We also find that these firms also often consider their main market to be characterised by rapidly-changing technologies where higher competition also implies higher innovation.
    Keywords: Multiple or Simultaneous Equation Models: Models with Panel Data; Longitudinal Data; Spatial Time Series; Multiple or Simultaneous Equation Models: Discrete Regression and Qualitative Choice Models; Discrete Regressors; Proportions; Innovation and Invention: Processes and Incentives; Management of Technological Innovation and R&D; Technological Change: Government Policy;
    JEL: O31 O32 O38 C33 C35
    Date: 2015
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:unm:unumer:2015001&r=ino
  4. By: Dessi, Roberta; Yin, Nina
    Abstract: This paper explores a new role for venture capitalists, as knowledge intermediaries. A venture capital investor can communicate valuable knowledge to an entrepreneur, facilitating innovation. The venture capitalist can also communicate the entrepreneur's innovative knowledge to other portfolio companies. We study the costs and benefits of these two forms of knowledge transfer, and their implications for investment, innovation, and product market competition. The model also sheds light on the choice between venture capital and other forms of finance, and the determinants of the decision to seek patent protection for innovations. Our analysis provides a rationale for the use of contingencies (specifically, patent approval) in VC contracts documented by Kaplan and Stromberg (2003), and for recent evidence on patterns of syndication among venture capitalists.
    Keywords: venture capital, knowledge intermediaries, contracts, innovation, competition, patents.
    JEL: D82 D86 G24 L22
    Date: 2015–02
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:tse:wpaper:29010&r=ino
  5. By: Leppälä, Samuli (Cardiff Business School)
    Abstract: This paper presents a Cournot oligopoly model with R&D spillovers both within and across industries. The aim is to provide an appropriate theoretical foundation for three different hypotheses regarding the impact of the local production structure on innovation and output, as well as addressing mixed empirical results in this area. Both the effective R&D and total industry output are shown to increase with the variety of industries, which is aligned with Jacobs externalities. With respect to the concentration, the outcome is more ambiguous, where it depends on the variety, both spillover rates, and the R&D efficiency. If the variety is limited, then partial support is given to both Marshall-Arrow-Romer externalities in the case of effective R&D, and to Porter externalities in the case of the total industry output. The use of a relative rather than an absolute measure of variety is also shown to be important.
    Keywords: concentration; innovation; knowledge spillover; regional economy; variety
    JEL: O33 R11 L13
    Date: 2015–02
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cdf:wpaper:2015/3&r=ino
  6. By: Bircan, Cagatay; de Haas, R. (Tilburg University, Center For Economic Research)
    Abstract: We exploit historical and contemporaneous variation in local credit markets across Russia to identify the impact of credit constraints on firm-level innovation. We find that access to bank credit helps firms to adopt existing products and production processes that are new to them. They introduce these technologies either with the help of suppliers and clients or by acquiring external know-how. We find no evidence that bank credit also stimulates firm innovation through in-house R&D. This suggests that banks can facilitate the discussion of technologies within developing countries but that their role in pushing the technological frontier is limited.
    Keywords: Credit Constraints; firn innovation; technological change
    JEL: D22 G21 O12 O31
    Date: 2015
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:tiu:tiucen:d7a436de-83f6-4551-aaf9-06ec05d63b2b&r=ino
  7. By: Crespi G.A.; Tacsir E.; Vargas F. (UNU-MERIT)
    Abstract: Innovation is fundamental for economic catching-up and raising living standards. Evidence demonstrate a virtuous circle in which RD spending, innovation, productivity, and per capita income mutually reinforce each other and lead to long-term, sustained growth rates and may foster job creation. Previous evidence highlights that Latin America and the Caribbean LAC has great potential to benefit from investment and policies that foster innovation. However, one important limitation of previous research on innovation in LAC is the absence of harmonised and comparable indicators across the different countries. This seriously limits the possibility to infer policy conclusions that are not affected by country specificities with respect to data quality and coverage. Also, most of this research is focused on estimating firm level correlations without attempting to identify market failures or other limitations which harm innovation investment or which could guide policy. In this paper, a wide range of innovation indicators are analysed in order to describe the innovation behaviour of manufacturing firms in LAC using the Enterprise Survey ES database. Our objective is to understand the main characteristics of innovative firms in LAC and to gather new evidence with regard to the nature of the innovation process in the region. In this paper we apply a structural model based on Crepon, Duget and Mairesse 1998, to estimate the determinants of innovation RD and its impact on total factor productivity. We pay special attention to whether there is heterogeneity in the effects of investments in innovation on productivity and whether there is any evidence of spillovers that could guide policy design. We found strong evidence concerning the relationships between innovation input and output, and innovation output and productivity. We found that private returns to innovation depend on the type of innovation, being larger for product than process innovation. Furthermore, we found some evidence that spillovers are stronger in the case of product than process innovation. It was also found that innovation returns are higher for the most productive firms. This increasing relationship between returns and productivity is not consistent with an interpretation that financial constraints cause more harm to low productivity firms. However, it is consistent with alternative interpretations about the lack of innovation opportunities in the case of low productivity firms or that low private returns are the results of poor appropriability.
    Keywords: Microeconomic Analyses of Economic Development; Industrialization; Manufacturing and Service Industries; Choice of Technology; Innovation and Invention: Processes and Incentives; Technological Change: Choices and Consequences; Diffusion Processes; Economic Growth and Aggregate Productivity: General;
    JEL: O12 O14 O31 O33 O40
    Date: 2014
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:unm:unumer:2014092&r=ino
  8. By: Michael S. Kinch (Instituto Nacional da Propriedade Industrial, Assessoria de Assuntos Econômicos, Brazil.); Julio Raffo (Economics and Statistics Division, World Intellectual Property Organization, Geneva, Switzerland.)
    Abstract: An analysis of FDA-approved new molecular entities reveals dynamism in terms of new innovation. An assessment of the first patent for each drug reveals that the pharmaceutical industry, particularly large, established companies in North America, tend to dominate the field. Over the past 10-15 years, European and Asian organizations have begun to close the gap. A dynamic inventive environment in drug discovery is suggested by the fact that NMEs for biologics or awarded to biotechnology companies often have inventors from the pharmaceutical and academic sectors. Whereas inventors continue to found biotechnology companies at a steady rate, recent trends suggest these inventors more often come from the private sector.
    Keywords: FDA, Patent, Intellectual Property, Firm founder.
    Date: 2015–02
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:wip:wpaper:24&r=ino
  9. By: Gianni Guastella; Frank van Oort
    Abstract: In agglomeration studies, the effects of various regional externalities related to knowledge spillovers remain largely unclear. To explain innovation clustering, scholars emphasize the contribution of Localized Knowledge Spillovers (LKS) and, specifically when estimating the Knowledge Production Function (KPF), of (interregional) research spillovers. However, less attention is paid to other causes of spatial heterogeneity. In applied works, spatial association in data is econometrically related to evidence of research spillovers. This paper argues that, in a KPF setting, omitting spatial heterogeneity might lead to biased estimates of the effect of research spillovers. As an empirical test, a spatial KPF is estimated using EU25 regional data, including a spatial trend to control for unexplained spatial variation in innovation. Accounting for geographical characteristics substantially weakens evidence of interregional research spillovers.
    Keywords: Generalized Additive Models, Knowledge Spillovers, Regional Innovation, European Union
    JEL: R12 R58
    Date: 2015–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:egu:wpaper:1506&r=ino
  10. By: Jürgen Bitzer (University of Oldenburg - Department of Economics & ZenTra); Erkan Gören (University of Oldenburg - Department of Economics); Sanne Hiller (Aarhus University - Department of Economics and Business)
    Abstract: This paper explores the role of immigrant employees for a firm’s capability to absorb international knowledge. Using matched employer-employee data from Denmark for the years 1996 to 2009, we are able to show that non-Danish employees from technological advanced countries contribute significantly to a firm’s economic output through their ability to access international knowledge. The empirical results suggest that the immigrants’ impact increases if they come from technological advanced countries, have a high educational level, and are employed in high-skilled positions.
    Keywords: R&D Spillovers, Absorptive Capacity, Firm-Level Analysis, Foreign Workers, Immigrants
    JEL: D20 J82 L20 O30
    Date: 2015–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:zen:wpaper:49&r=ino
  11. By: Lilas Demmou; Andreas Wörgötter
    Abstract: The labour market in Russia is very flexible. Firms adjust to economic shocks through wage cuts, working hour reductions and minimisation of non-wage labour costs. Workers react by changing jobs. This results in a high and stable overall employment rate, but also high wage inequality, informality and labour turnover, which limits incentives for firms to invest in human capital and productivity improvements.<P> While educational attainment is very high, the education system needs to be strengthened to respond to the needs of a skill-based economy. School-employer cooperation is low and opportunities for higher education are unequally distributed. Adequate funding for education institutions is not assured everywhere while inefficiencies persist.<P> Private spending on innovation is very low and Russia underperforms in terms of scientific outputs and patents. Support for low-tech innovation and technology adoption, especially among SMEs is narrow because of a bias towards large and high-tech projects, which however are only loosely related to Russian manufacturing capacity. Reform of the public R&D sector is incomplete, notably with respect to strengthening funding on a competitive basis.<P>Stimuler la productivité en Russie : Les compétences, l'éducation et l'innovation<BR>Le marché du travail en Russie est très flexible. Les entreprises s’ajustent face aux chocs économiques grâce à une réduction des salaires, des heures de travail, et des coûts non salariaux. Les travailleurs réagissent en changeant d'emploi. Il en résulte un taux d'emploi global élevé et stable, mais également un niveau élevé des inégalités salariales, de l’emploi informel et du taux de rotation de la main d’oeuvre, ce qui limite les incitations pour les entreprises à investir dans le capital humain et l'amélioration de la productivité. Bien que le niveau de scolarisation soit très élevé, le système d'éducation doit être renforcé pour répondre aux besoins d'une économie fondée sur les compétences. La coopération entre les entreprises et le système éducatif est faible et les opportunités d’accès à l’éducation supérieure sont inégalement réparties. Un financement adéquat des établissements d’enseignement n'est pas assuré sur l’ensemble du territoire alors que des zones d’inefficacités persistent. Les dépenses privées consacrées à l'innovation sont très faibles et les performances de la Russie en termes de production scientifiques et de brevets sont insatisfaisantes. Le soutien aux innovations à faible contenu technologique et à l'adoption des technologies, en particulier dans les PME, est faible en raison d'un biais en faveur des grands projets et des projets high-tech, qui ne sont cependant que faiblement liés aux capacités de production manufacturière russe. La réforme du secteur public de la R&D est incomplète, notamment en ce qui concerne le rôle joué par les financements accordés sur des principes de compétitivité.
    Keywords: human capital, education, innovation, active labour market policies, flexibility, inequality, PISA, VET, life-long learning, labour turnover, skills matching, collective bargaining, trade unions, unemployment benefits, prestations de chômage, adéquation des compétences, convention collective, capital humain, inégalités, PISA, politiques actives du marché du travail, innovations, rotation de la main d’oeuvre, enseignement et formation professionnelle, éducation, syndicats, flexibilité, formation continue
    JEL: I2 J21 J24 J31 J50 J60 O3
    Date: 2015–03–05
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:oec:ecoaaa:1189-en&r=ino
  12. By: Claudia Steinwender
    Abstract: A variety of empirical and theoretical trade papers have suggested and documented a positive impact of trade on the productivity of firms. However, there is less consensus about the underlying mechanism at work. While trade papers focus on access to export markets, other papers stress the importance of import competition. Since imports and exports (and even tariffs affecting either) are usually highly correlated, it is unclear which mechanism the existing empirical papers uncover. This paper conducts a “horse race” between export opportunities and import competition. Using Spanish firm level data, instrumenting for exports and imports with tariff changes and controlling for selection, I find robust evidence that access to export markets leads to productivity increases, but only for firms that were already highly productive before. The evidence on import competition is weaker. If anything, initially low-tech firms manage to increase their productivity in response to increased competition from abroad. The latter finding is at odds with most trade models, so I propose a model incorporating non-profit maximizing managers to reconcile theory with the evidence. Empirically, I find that all productivity upgrades are driven by increased R&D, patenting, and product innovation. Access to export markets also leads to the adaptation of foreign technologies. There is no evidence that either mechanism leads to increased full time employment, instead full time workers seem to be replaced by part-time or temporary workers.
    Keywords: import competition; technical change; productivity; exporting
    JEL: F12 F13 F14 L25
    Date: 2015–02
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ehl:lserod:61154&r=ino
  13. By: Antonio Acconcia (Università di Napoli Federico II and CSEF); Claudia Cantabene (Seconda Università di Napoli)
    Abstract: In concurrence with the recent credit crisis, the Italian government tried to stimulate R&D expenditures through tax credit. We rely on this policy to identify the firm response to an exogenous countercyclical fiscal shock. Large heterogeneity by the size of cash is observed for firms in traditional industries. The tax credit caused higher expenditures for firms with relative large cash holdings. For firms characterized by low levels of cash, the stimulus was instead mainly useful to counteract the negative effects of the credit crunch. No impact is observed among high-tech firms consistent with their tendency to smooth R&D. Our findings complement those on household response to tax rebate in US and Italy, offering new evidence for evaluating fiscal stimulus programmes. Classification-E21, E62
    Keywords: Crisis, Fiscal Stimulus, Investment-cash Sensitivity, Quasi-experiment, R&D
    Date: 2015–02–28
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:sef:csefwp:392&r=ino
  14. By: Ho Fai Chan; Ali Sina Onder; Benno Torgler
    Abstract: Despite much in-depth investigation of factors influencing this evolution in various scientific fields, our knowledge about how efficiency or creativity is linked to the longevity of collaborative relationships remains very limited. We explore what Nobel laureates' coauthorship patterns reveal about the nature of scientific collaborations looking at the intensity and success of scientific collaborations across fields and across laureates' collaborative lifecycles in physics, chemistry, and physiology/medicine. We find that more collaboration with the same researcher is actually no better for advancing creativity: publications produced early in a sequence of repeated collaborations with a given coauthor tend to be published better and cited more than papers that come later in the collaboration with the same coauthor. Thus, our results indicate that scientific collaboration involves conceptual complementarities that may erode over a sequence of repeated interactions.
    Keywords: Innovation; Scientific Collaboration; Team Formation; Nobel Laureates
    JEL: D20 O30
    Date: 2015–03–04
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:qut:qubewp:wp032&r=ino
  15. By: Hector Hernandez (JRC-IPTS); Alexander Tuebke (JRC-IPTS); Fernando Hervas (JRC-IPTS); Antonio Vezzani (JRC-IPTS); Sara Amoroso (JRC-IPTS)
    Abstract: The 2013 "EU Industrial R&D Scoreboard" (the Scoreboard) contains economic and financial data of the world's top 2000 companies ranked by their investments in research and development (R&D). The sample contains 527 companies based in the EU and 1474 companies based elsewhere. The Scoreboard data are drawn from the latest available companies' accounts, i.e. the fiscal year 2012.
    Keywords: economy, investment, research and development
    Date: 2013–12
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ipt:iptwpa:jrc85411&r=ino

This nep-ino issue is ©2015 by Steffen Lippert. It is provided as is without any express or implied warranty. It may be freely redistributed in whole or in part for any purpose. If distributed in part, please include this notice.
General information on the NEP project can be found at http://nep.repec.org. For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese at <director@nep.repec.org>. Put “NEP” in the subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.