nep-ino New Economics Papers
on Innovation
Issue of 2012‒03‒14
nine papers chosen by
Steffen Lippert
University of Otago, Dunedin

  1. Asymmetric R&D alliances and coopetitive games By Carfì, David; Bagileri, Daniela; Dagnino, Gianbattista
  2. Patent Protection, Technological Change and Wage Inequality: Theory By Shiyuan Pan; Tailong Li; Heng-fu Zou
  3. Patent Protection, Technological Change and Wage Inequality: Application By Shiyuan Pan; Tailong Li; Ying Zhou; Heng-fu Zou
  4. Highly skilled temporary return, technological change and Innovation: The Case of the TRQN Project in Afghanistan By Kuschminder, Katie; Siegel, Melissa
  5. International R&D spillovers, absorptive capacity and relative backwardness: a panel smooth transition regression model By Andrea Fracasso; Giuseppe Vittucci Marzetti
  6. Smithian Growth Through Creative Organization By Legros, Patrick; Newman, Andrew F; Proto, Eugenio
  7. Innovation in EU merger control: walking the talk By Reinhilde Veugelers
  8. Technological Abundance for Global Agriculture: The Role of Biotechnology By Juma, Calestous
  9. Knowledge-based economies and the institutional environment By Schilirò, Daniele

  1. By: Carfì, David; Bagileri, Daniela; Dagnino, Gianbattista
    Abstract: In this paper we show how the study of asymmetric R\&D alliances, that are those between young and small firms and large and MNEs firms for knowledge exploration and/or exploitation, requires the adoption of a coopetitive framework which consider both collaboration and competition. We draw upon the literature on asymmetric R&D collaboration and coopetition to propose a mathematical model for the coopetitive games which is particularly suitable for exploring asymmetric R&D alliances.
    Keywords: R&D alliances; coopetitive games
    JEL: D7 M1 D74 C7 O32 M54 O3 J5
    Date: 2012
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:37095&r=ino
  2. By: Shiyuan Pan (School of Economics and Center for Research of Private Economy, Zhejiang University); Tailong Li (School of Economics & Management, Zhejiang Sci-Tech University); Heng-fu Zou (Central University of Finance and Economics, CEMA; Wuhan University IAS; Peking University; China Development Bank)
    Abstract: We develop a directed-technological-change model to address the issue of the optimal patent system and investigate how the optimal patent system influences the direction of technological change and the inequality of wage, where patents are categorized as skill- and labor-complementary. The major results are: (i) Finite patent breadth maximizes the social welfare level; (ii) Optimal patent breadth increases with the amount of skilled (unskilled) workers; (iii) Optimal patent protection is skill-biased, because an increase in the amount of skilled workers increases the dynamic benefits of the protection for skill-complementary patents via the economy of scale of skill-complementary technology; (iv) Skill-biased patent protection skews inventions towards skills, thus increasing wage inequality.
    Keywords: Patent Breadth, Skill-Biased Patent Protection, Skill-Biased Technological Change, Wage Inequality, Economic Growth
    JEL: O31 O34 J31
    Date: 2012–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cuf:wpaper:537&r=ino
  3. By: Shiyuan Pan (School of Economics and Center for Research of Private Economy, Zhejiang University); Tailong Li (School of Economics & Management, Zhejiang Sci-Tech University); Ying Zhou (School of Economics, Zhejiang University); Heng-fu Zou (Central University of Finance and Economics, CEMA; Wuhan University IAS; Peking University; China Development Bank)
    Abstract: We develop a directed-technological-change model to address the issue of the optimal patent system and investigate how the optimal patent system influences the direction of technological change and the inequality of wage, where patents are categorized as skill- and labor-complementary. The major results are: (i) Finite patent breadth maximizes the social welfare level; (ii) Optimal patent breadth increases with the amount of skilled (unskilled) workers; (iii) Optimal patent protection is skill-biased, because an increase in the amount of skilled workers increases the dynamic benefits of the protection for skill-complementary patents via the economy of scale of skill-complementary technology; (iv) Skill-biased patent protection skews inventions towards skills, thus increasing wage inequality; And, (v) international trade leads to strong protection for skill-complementary patents, hence increasing skill premia.
    Keywords: Patent Breadth, Skill-Biased Patent Protection, Skill-Biased Technological Change, Wage Inequality, Growth
    JEL: O31 O34 J31
    Date: 2012–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cuf:wpaper:538&r=ino
  4. By: Kuschminder, Katie (UNU-MERIT/MGSoG, Maastricht University); Siegel, Melissa (UNU-MERIT/MGSoG, Maastricht University)
    Abstract: Using the specific case of the International Organization for Migration's (IOM) Temporary Return of Qualified Nationals (TRQN) project, this paper illustrates the effect the short-term return of highly qualified migrants abroad can have on capacity building in the origin country through knowledge transfer, innovation and technological change. The paper specifically examines the needs, expectations and delivery of knowledge through the TRQN project in Afghanistan.
    Keywords: migration, return migration, innovation, technological change, migration and development, Afghanistan
    JEL: O33 O15 J24
    Date: 2012
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:dgr:unumer:2012017&r=ino
  5. By: Andrea Fracasso; Giuseppe Vittucci Marzetti
    Abstract: We investigate how the country’s absorptive capacity and relative backwardness affect the impact of international R&D spillovers on domestic Total Factor Productivity (TFP). To account for nonlinearities, we adopt a Panel Smooth Transition Regression (PSTR) approach, where the country’s elasticity of TFP to foreign R&D stock is allowed to change smoothly across various identified extreme values, and this change is related to observable transition variables: human capital (capturing the country’s absorptive capacity) and relative backwardness. The results suggest that absorptive capacity is positively associated with international R&D spillovers. In addition, and in contrast with previous results, relative backwardness has a negative and significant impact on them.
    Keywords: Absorptive capacity, International R&D spillovers, Nonlinear panel, Smooth Transition Regression, Total Factor Productivity
    JEL: C23 C24 F43 O30 O47
    Date: 2012
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:trn:utwpde:1203&r=ino
  6. By: Legros, Patrick (ECARES and CEPR); Newman, Andrew F (Boston University and CEPR); Proto, Eugenio (University of warwick)
    Abstract: We consider a model in which appropriate organization fosters innovation, but because of contractibility problems, this benefit cannot be internalized. The organizational design element we focus on is the division of labor, which as Adam Smith argued, facilitates invention by observers of the production process. However, entrepreneurs choose its level only to facilitate monitoring their workers. Whether there is innovation depends on the interaction of the markets for labor and for inventions. A high level of specialization is chosen when the wage share is low. But low wage shares arise only when there are few entrepreneurs, which limits the market for innovations therefore and discourages inventive activity. When there are many entrepreneurs, the innovation market is large, but the rate of invention is low because there is little specialization. Rapid technological progress therefore requires a balance between these opposing e ects, which occurs with a moderate relative scarcity of entrepreneurs and workers. In a dynamic version of the model in which a credit constraint limits entry into entrepreneurship, this relative scarcity depends on the wealth distribution, which evolves endogenously. There is an inverted-U relation between growth rates driven by innovation and the level of inequality. Institutional improvements have ambiguous effects on growth. In light of the model, we offer a reassessment of the mechanism by which organizational innovations such as the factory may have spawned the industrial revolution. Key words: factory system ; industrial revolution ; technological change ; contracts
    Date: 2012
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:wrk:warwec:981&r=ino
  7. By: Reinhilde Veugelers
    Abstract: European Union policymakers have in principle put innovation at the heart of competitiveness, in particular in the Europe 2020 strategy. But in merger control, assessments of the innovation effects of mergers are inadequate, even though mergers and acquisitions can have a significant impact on the development of the structure of an industry, and on its capability to innovate. EU merger control rules include scope for assessing the innovation effects of mergers, but in practice, the European Commission's directorate-general for competition (DG COMP) is not â??walking the talkâ??. Innovation effects are only assessed when claimed by parties to a merger, and this happens rarely. Where innovation effects have been claimed, they have not been decisive in any case, meaning DG COMP has not considered them important enough to influence its decision. A framework should be put in place that makes the reporting of efficiency-related information by the merging parties mandatory, so that innovation effects can be properly assessed for all mergers. In addition, models can be used to make an assessment of the longer-term innovation effects of a merger, and to help inform decision-making. The author acknowledges the excellent research assistance of Joan de Solà-Morales and Hendrik Meder, and would like to thank Lars-Hendrik Röller for discussing and commenting on earlier versions of the paper.
    Date: 2012–02
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:bre:polcon:708&r=ino
  8. By: Juma, Calestous (Harvard University)
    Abstract: Science and innovation have always been the key forces behind agricultural growth in particular and economic transformation in general. More specifically, the ability to add value to agricultural production via the application of scientific knowledge to entrepreneurial activities stands out as one of the most important lessons of economic history. The Green Revolution played a critical role in helping to overcome chronic food shortages in Latin America and Asia. The Green Revolution was a result of both the creation of new institutional arrangements aimed at using existing technology to improve agricultural productivity, as well as new scientific breakthroughs leading to superior agricultural inputs, particularly improved strains of wheat and rice. In the wake of the recent global economic crisis and continually high food prices, the international community is reviewing its outlook on human welfare and prosperity. Much of the current concern on how to foster development and prosperity in developing countries reflects the consequences of recent neglect of sustainable agriculture and infrastructure as drivers of development. But all is not lost. Instead, those developing countries that have not yet fully embraced agricultural technology now have the chance to benefit from preexisting scientific advances in agriculture, particularly in biotechnology. Areas of the developing world lagging in the utilization and accumulation of technology have the ability not only to catch up to industrial leaders in biotechnology, but also to attain their own level of research growth.
    Date: 2012–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ecl:harjfk:rwp12-008&r=ino
  9. By: Schilirò, Daniele
    Abstract: Modern economies are increasingly based on knowledge and, more generally, on the intangible assets that favour the economic development. Knowledge-based economies are founded on increasing specialization, research, innovation and learning. The change towards a knowledge-based economy is happening on a global scale, a transformation is taking place in all advanced industrialised economies and many developing economies are also aspiring to reach this target. Knowledge-based economies require some critical requisites to become real and efficient economies. These are the four pillars: education and training, innovation, information infrastructure, the institutional regime. This contribution will focus mainly on one of those pillars: the institutional environment. Thus, after examining the definition and the characteristics of a knowledge-based economy, it focuses on the relationship between knowledge-based economies and the role of institutions. Institutions and the institutional environment play a key role in the development of a knowledge economy, so they do matter. The paper argues that various institutional changes must be introduced and these institutional changes that need to be made will involve the public and private sector, as it has been in the case of the Finland’s economy. In addition, because of the difficulties for the institutions to build and establish itself over time, it is necessary a certain degree of flexibility in the institutional regime and, hence, the ability to respond to uncertainties.
    Keywords: knowledge-based economy; institutional environment; institutions; innovation; learning; development
    JEL: O38 O30 D02 D20 O32 D83
    Date: 2010–11
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:37138&r=ino

This nep-ino issue is ©2012 by Steffen Lippert. It is provided as is without any express or implied warranty. It may be freely redistributed in whole or in part for any purpose. If distributed in part, please include this notice.
General information on the NEP project can be found at http://nep.repec.org. For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese at <director@nep.repec.org>. Put “NEP” in the subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.