nep-hpe New Economics Papers
on History and Philosophy of Economics
Issue of 2012‒09‒16
twelve papers chosen by
Erik Thomson
University of Manitoba

  1. Too smart to be selfish? Measures of cognitive ability, social preferences, and consistency By Chen, Chia-Ching; Chiu, I-Ming; Smith, John; Yamada, Tetsuji
  2. Representations Of Positive Projections On Lipschitz Vector By Omer Edhan
  3. The Effect of Perspective on Unethical Behavior By Amos Schurr; Ilana Ritov; Yaakov Kareev; Judith Avrahami
  4. Continuous-time Stochastic Games By Abraham Neyman
  5. On the Convergence to Nash Bargaining Solution for Endogenous Bargaining Protocols By Herings P. Jean-Jacques; Britz Volker; Predtetchinski Arkadi
  6. Continuous-Time Stochastic Games of Fixed Duration By Yehuda (John) Levy
  7. An experimental study of mixed strategy equilibria in simultaneous price-quantity games By Daniel Cracau; Benjamin Franz
  8. Time as a Medium of Reward in Three Social Preference Experiments By Noussair, C.N.; Stoop, J.T.R.
  9. Values of Exact Market Games By Omer Edhan
  10. Spectrum Value for Coalitional Games By Mikel Alvarez-Mozos; Ziv Hellman; Eyal Winter
  11. The Strategic Impact of Higher-Order Beliefs By Yi-Chun Chen; Alfredo Di Tillio; Eduardo Faingold; Siyang Xiong
  12. Sovereign Debt Restructurings 1950 - 2010: Literature Survey, Data, and Stylized Facts By Christoph Trebesch; Michael G Papaioannou; Udaibir S. Das

  1. By: Chen, Chia-Ching; Chiu, I-Ming; Smith, John; Yamada, Tetsuji
    Abstract: Although there is an increasing interest in examining the relationship between cognitive ability and economic behavior, less is known about the relationship between cognitive ability and social preferences. We investigate the relationship between consequential measures of cognitive ability and measures of social preferences. We have data on a series of small-stakes dictator-type decisions, known as Social Value Orientation (SVO), in addition to choices in a larger-stakes dictator game. We also have access to the grade point averages (GPA) and SAT (formerly referred to as the Scholastic Aptitude Test) outcomes of our subjects. We find that subjects who perform better on the Math portion of the SAT are more generous in both the dictator game and the SVO measure. By contrast we find that subjects with a higher GPA are more selfish in the dictator game and more generous according to the SVO. We also find some evidence that the subjects with higher GPA and higher SAT outcomes offer more consistent responses. Our results involving GPA and social preferences complement previous work which employ measures of cognitive ability which are sensitive to the intrinsic motivation of the subject. Our results involving SAT scores are without precedent in the literature and suggest that measures of cognitive ability, which are less sensitive to the intrinsic motivation of the subject, are positively related to generosity.
    Keywords: dictator game; Social Value Orientation; altruism; intelligence
    JEL: D64 C91
    Date: 2012–09–05
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:41078&r=hpe
  2. By: Omer Edhan
    Abstract: Among the single-valued solution concepts studied in cooperative game theory and economics, those which are also positive projections play an important role. The value, semivalues, and quasivalues of a cooperative game are several examples of solution concepts which are positive projections. These solution concepts are known to have many important applications in economics. In many applications the specific positive projection discussed is represented as an expectation of marginal contributions of agents to ``random" coalitions. Usually these representations are used to characterize positive projections obeying certain additional axioms. It is thus of interest to study the representation theory of positive projections and its relation with some common axioms. We study positive projections defined over certain spaces of nonatomic Lipschitz vector measure games. To this end, we develop a general notion of ``calculus" for such games, which in a manner extends the notion of the Radon-Nykodim derivative for measures. We prove several representation results for positive projections, which essentially state that the image of a game under the action of a positive projection can be represented as an averaging of its derivative w.r.t. some vector measure. We then introduce a specific calculus for the space $\mathcal{CON}$ generated by concave, monotonically nondecreasing, and Lipschitz continuous functions of finitely many nonatomic probability measures. We study in detail the properties of the resulting representations of positive projections on $\mathcal{CON}$ and especially those of values on $\mathcal{CON}$. The latter results are of great importance in various applications in economics.
    Date: 2012–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:huj:dispap:dp624&r=hpe
  3. By: Amos Schurr; Ilana Ritov; Yaakov Kareev; Judith Avrahami
    Abstract: In two experiments, we explored how the perspective through which individuals view their decisions influences their moral behavior. To do this we employed a computerized “Is that the answer you had in mind?” trivial-pursuit style game. The game challenges individuals’ integrity because cheating during play cannot be detected. Perspective, whether local or global, was manipulated: In Experiment 1 the choice procedure was used to evoke a local or an integrative perspective of one’s choices, whereas in Experiment 2, perspective was manipulated through priming. Across all the experiments, we observed that when given an incentive to cheat, the adoption of a local perspective increased cheating, as evidenced by overall higher reported success rates. These findings have clear implications for explaining and controlling behavior in other situations (e.g., exercising, dieting) in which the perspective one takes is a matter of choice.
    Date: 2012–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:huj:dispap:dp620&r=hpe
  4. By: Abraham Neyman
    Abstract: Every continuous-time stochastic game with finitely many states and actions has a uniform and limiting-average equilibrium payoff.
    Date: 2012–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:huj:dispap:dp616&r=hpe
  5. By: Herings P. Jean-Jacques; Britz Volker; Predtetchinski Arkadi (METEOR)
    Abstract: We consider non-cooperative multilateral bargaining games with endogenous bargaining protocols.Under an endogenous protocol, the probability with which a player becomes the proposer in a roundof bargaining depends on the identity of the player who previously rejected. An important exampleis the frequently studied rejector-becomes-proposer protocol. We focus on subgame perfectequilibria in stationary strategies which are shown to exist and to be efficient. Equilibriumproposals do not depend on the probability to proposeconditional on the rejection by another player, though equilibrium acceptance sets do depend onthese probabilities. Next we consider the limit, as the bargaining friction vanishes. In case noplayer has a positive probability to propose conditional on his rejection, each player receiveshis utopia payoff conditional on being recognized and equilibrium payoffs are in general Paretoinefficient. Otherwise, equilibrium proposals of all players converge to a weighted NashBargaining Solution, where the weights are determined by the probability to propose conditional ona rejection.
    Keywords: microeconomics ;
    Date: 2012
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:dgr:umamet:2012030&r=hpe
  6. By: Yehuda (John) Levy
    Abstract: We study non-zero-sum continuous-time stochastic games, also known as continuous-time Markov games, of fixed duration. We concentrate on Markovian strategies. We show by way of example that equilibria need not exist in Markovian strategies, but they always exist in Markovian public-signal correlated strategies. To do so, we develop criteria for a strategy profile to be an equilibrium via differential inclusions, both directly and also by modeling continuous-time stochastic as differential games and using the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equations. We also give an interpretation of equilibria in mixed strategies in continuous-time, and show that approximate equilibria always exist.
    Date: 2012–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:huj:dispap:dp617&r=hpe
  7. By: Daniel Cracau (Faculty of Economics and Management, Otto-von-Guericke University Magdeburg); Benjamin Franz (Mathematical Institute, University of Oxford)
    Abstract: We study oligopoly games with firms competing in prices and quantities at the same time. We systematically compare our experimental results to the theoretical predictions using the mixed strategy equilibria for linear demand functions. For the duopoly game, we observe that the mixed strategy equilibrium predicts average outcomes better than Cournot and Bertrand do. Subjects' price choices are mainly between marginal cost and monopoly level but do not follow the equilibrium distribution. Although average prices and profits are above theoretical values, we do not observe a high level of collusion as expected in the literature. By comparing simulations based on the mixed strategy equilibrium to our experimental outcomes, we conclude that in this game price setting can be explained by strategic reaction to preceding round results. In contrast to the equilibrium prediction, we observe a decrease in prices and negative average profits for the triopoly game.
    Keywords: Price-Quantity Competition; Mixed Strategy Equilibria; Experimental Economics; Learning Direction Theory
    JEL: D43 L11
    Date: 2012–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:mag:wpaper:120017&r=hpe
  8. By: Noussair, C.N.; Stoop, J.T.R. (Tilburg University, Center for Economic Research)
    Abstract: Abstract: We report results from three well-known experimental paradigms, where we use time, rather than money, as the salient component of subjects’ incentives. The three experiments, commonly employed to study social preferences, are the dictator game, the ultimatum game and the trust game. All subjects in a session earn the same participation fee, but their choices affect the time at which they are permitted to leave the laboratory, with decisions typically associated with greater own payoff translating into an earlier departure. The modal proposal in both the dictator and ultimatum games is an equal split of the waiting time. In the trust game, there is substantial trust and reciprocity. Overall, social preferences are evident in time allocation decisions. Received laboratory results from dictator, ultimatum, and trust games are robust to the change in reward medium, though there is some suggestive evidence that decisions are even more prosocial with respect to time than money.
    Keywords: dictator game;ultimatum game;trust game;time.
    JEL: C70 C91 D63 D64
    Date: 2012
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:dgr:kubcen:2012068&r=hpe
  9. By: Omer Edhan
    Abstract: We prove that a single-valued solution of perfectly competitive TU economies underling nonatomic exact market games is uniquely determined as the Mertens value by four plausible value-related axioms. Since the Mertens value is always a core element, this result provides an axiomatization of the Mertens value as a core-selection. Previous works in this direction assumed the economies to be either di erentiable (e.g., Dubey and Neyman [9]) or of uniform nite-type (e.g., Haimanko [14]). Our work does not assume that, thus it contributes to the axiomatic study of payo s in perfectly competitive economies (or values of their derived market games) in general. In fact, this is the rst contribution in this direction.
    Date: 2012–09
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:huj:dispap:dp627&r=hpe
  10. By: Mikel Alvarez-Mozos; Ziv Hellman; Eyal Winter
    Abstract: Assuming a `spectrum' or ordering on the players of a coalitional game, as in a political spectrum in a parliamentary situation, we consider a variation of the Shapley value in which coalitions may only be formed if they are connected with respect to the spectrum. This results in a naturally asymmetric power index in which positioning along the spectrum is critical. We present both a characterisation of this value by means of properties and combinatoric formulae for calculating it. In simple majority games, the greatest power accrues to `moderate' players who are located neither at the extremes of the spectrum nor in its centre. In supermajority games, power increasingly accrues towards the extremes, and in unaninimity games all power is held by the players at the extreme of the spectrum.
    Date: 2012–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:huj:dispap:dp618&r=hpe
  11. By: Yi-Chun Chen (Dept. of Economics, National University of Singapore); Alfredo Di Tillio (IGIR and Dept. of Economics, Universita Luigi Bocconi); Eduardo Faingold (Cowles Foundation, Yale University); Siyang Xiong (Dept. of Economics, Rice University)
    Abstract: Previous research has established that the predictions made by game theory about strategic behavior in incomplete information games are quite sensitive to the assumptions made about the players' infinite hierarchies of beliefs. We evaluate the severity of this robustness problem by characterizing conditions on the primitives of the model -- the players’ hierarchies of beliefs -- for the strategic behavior of a given Harsanyi type to be approximated by the strategic behavior of (a sequence of) perturbed types. This amounts to providing characterizations of the strategic topologies of Dekel, Fudenberg, and Morris (2006) in terms of beliefs. We apply our characterizations to a variety of questions concerning robustness to perturbations of higher-order beliefs, including genericity of common priors, and the connections between robustness of strategic behavior and the notion of common p-belief of Monderer and Samet (1989).
    Keywords: Games with incomplete information, Rationalizability, Higher-order beliefs, Robustness
    JEL: C70 C72
    Date: 2012–09
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cwl:cwldpp:1875&r=hpe
  12. By: Christoph Trebesch; Michael G Papaioannou; Udaibir S. Das
    Abstract: This paper provides a comprehensive survey of pertinent issues on sovereign debt restructurings, based on a newly constructed database. This is the first complete dataset of sovereign restructuring cases, covering the six decades from 1950–2010; it includes 186 debt exchanges with foreign banks and bondholders, and 447 bilateral debt agreements with the Paris Club. We present new stylized facts on the outcome and process of debt restructurings, including on the size of haircuts, creditor participation, and legal aspects. In addition, the paper summarizes the relevant empirical literature, analyzes recent restructuring episodes, and discusses ongoing debates on crisis resolution mechanisms, credit default swaps, and the role of collective action clauses.
    Keywords: Debt relief , Debt restructuring , Developing countries , Domestic debt , Emerging markets , Sovereign debt ,
    Date: 2012–08–14
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:imf:imfwpa:12/203&r=hpe

This nep-hpe issue is ©2012 by Erik Thomson. It is provided as is without any express or implied warranty. It may be freely redistributed in whole or in part for any purpose. If distributed in part, please include this notice.
General information on the NEP project can be found at http://nep.repec.org. For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese at <director@nep.repec.org>. Put “NEP” in the subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.