nep-hme New Economics Papers
on Heterodox Microeconomics
Issue of 2021‒03‒29
sixteen papers chosen by
Carlo D’Ippoliti
Università degli Studi di Roma “La Sapienza”

  1. Friedrich Hayek’s liberal dialectics By Claude Gamel
  2. An Introduction to Food Cooperatives in the Bekaa Valley, Lebanon: Territorial Actors and Potential Levers to Local Development Through Culinary Heritage By Rita Jalkh; Marc Dedeire; Melanie Requier Desjardins
  3. The Relation of Neoclassical Economics to other Disciplines: The case of Physics and Psychology By Stavros, Drakopoulos
  4. Metaphorical Analysis of Discourse on Early Saudi Attempts to Include Women in Unconventional Work Environments By Shrouq Al Maghlouth
  5. Does Gender Equality Translate into Economic Equality? Evidence from about 150 Nations By Michael A. Nelson; Rajeev K. Goel
  6. Is the Recession a ‘Shecession’? Gender Inequality in the Employment Effects of the COVID-19 Pandemic in Germany By Moehring, Katja; Reifenscheid, Maximiliane; Weiland, Andreas
  7. Gender and Social Networks on Bank Boards By Ann L. Owen; Judit Temesvary; Andrew Wei
  8. How Entry into Parenthood Shapes Gender Role Attitudes: New Evidence from Longitudinal UK Data By Elena Grinza; Francesco Devicienti; Mariacristina Rossi; Davide Vannoni
  9. Some Reflections on Financial Instability in Macro Agents-Based Models. Genealogy and Objectives By Muriel Dal Pont Legrand
  10. Deliberating on Climate Action: Insights from the French Citizens' Convention for Climate By Louis-Gaëtan Giraudet; Bénédicte Apouey; Hazem Arab; Simon Baeckelandt; Philippe Begout; Nicolas Berghmans; Nathalie Blanc; Jean-Yves Boulin; Eric Buge; Dimitri Courant; Amy Dahan; Adrien Fabre; Jean-Michel Fourniau; Maxime Gaborit; Laurence Granchamp; Hélène Guillemot; Laurent Jeanpierre; Hélène Landemore; Jean-François Laslier; Antonin Macé; Claire Mellier- Wilson; Sylvain Mounier; Théophile Pénigaud; Ana Povoas; Christiane Rafidinarivo; Bernard Reber; Romane Rozencwajg; Philippe Stamenkovic; Selma Tilikete; Solène Tournus
  11. Review of “The Routledge Handbook of the History of Women’s Economic Thought” by Kirsten Madden and Robert W. Dimand By May, Ann Mari
  12. Knowledge-Based Structural Change By Kevin Genna; Christian Ghiglino; Kazuo Nishimura; Alain Venditti
  13. Motivation Crowding in Peer Effects: The Effect of Solar Subsidies on Green Power Purchases By Andrea La Nauze
  14. Climate Change and Financial Stability By Celso Brunetti; Benjamin Dennis; Dylan Gates; Diana Hancock; David Ignell; Elizabeth K. Kiser; Gurubala Kotta; Anna Kovner; Richard J. Rosen; Nicholas K. Tabor
  15. Does a local knowledge base in Industry 3.0 foster diversification in Industry 4.0 technologies? Evidence from European regions By Matteo Laffi; Ron Boschma;
  16. Angst, Sorge, Tod: Über eine "Ökonomie der Sorge" in der Corona-Krise By Priddat, Birger P.

  1. By: Claude Gamel (LEST - Laboratoire d'économie et de sociologie du travail - AMU - Aix Marseille Université - CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique)
    Abstract: Although they lived a century apart, Hayek might be considered as the liberal counterpart of Marx: not only both carried out transdisciplinary studies but they also used a dialectic approach. According to Hayek, the evolution of human societies cannot remain under control because the "spontaneous social order" is opposed to "organisations", an opposition that rests upon a conflict between two kinds of rationality set at the epistemological level (I). That can only be overcome through the fine tracking of "abstract rules of just conduct" in the legal order (II). However Hayek's pessimistic view holds ground and this is the result of the divergence, in the field of economics, between the rules necessary for market order and a conception of justice within society that is too ambitious and can even be so corrosive as to destroy it (III). To conclude, we shall ask the question what act as safeguard nowadays so as to allow liberal societies to survive, as Hayek sought to guarantee.
    Abstract: Hayek peut être considéré, à un siècle de distance, comme l'homologue libéral de Marx, non seulement par le caractère transdisciplinaire de la réflexion, mais surtout par le recours à une démarche dialectique. Selon Hayek, l'évolution non maîtrisable des sociétés humaines oppose « ordre social spontané » et « organisations » et repose sur un conflit de « rationalité » d'ordre épistémologique (I). Cette opposition ne peut être surmontée, dans l'ordre juridique, qu'au prix du repérage délicat de « règles abstraites de juste conduite » (II). Le pessimisme propre à Hayek résulte alors, dans le champ de l'économie, de la divergence entre les règles nécessaires à l'ordre du marché et une conception trop ambitieuse de la justice en société qui risque de le détruire (III). D'où l'évocation, en conclusion, de la pertinence aujourd'hui des garde-fous à mettre en place, pour que, selon Hayek, les sociétés libérales puissent malgré tout survivre.
    Keywords: liberalism,dialectics,organisations,rules of just conduct,liberalisme,dialectique,ordre spontané,règles de juste conduite
    Date: 2021
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hal:journl:halshs-03158396&r=all
  2. By: Rita Jalkh (UMR ART-Dev - Acteurs, Ressources et Territoires dans le Développement - Cirad - Centre de Coopération Internationale en Recherche Agronomique pour le Développement - UPVM - Université Paul-Valéry - Montpellier 3 - UPVD - Université de Perpignan Via Domitia - UM - Université de Montpellier - CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique, CIHEAM-IAMM - Centre International de Hautes Etudes Agronomiques Méditerranéennes - Institut Agronomique Méditerranéen de Montpellier - CIHEAM - Centre International de Hautes Études Agronomiques Méditerranéennes); Marc Dedeire (UMR ART-Dev - Acteurs, Ressources et Territoires dans le Développement - Cirad - Centre de Coopération Internationale en Recherche Agronomique pour le Développement - UPVM - Université Paul-Valéry - Montpellier 3 - UPVD - Université de Perpignan Via Domitia - UM - Université de Montpellier - CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique); Melanie Requier Desjardins (CIHEAM-IAMM - Centre International de Hautes Etudes Agronomiques Méditerranéennes - Institut Agronomique Méditerranéen de Montpellier - CIHEAM - Centre International de Hautes Études Agronomiques Méditerranéennes)
    Abstract: Economic development approaches are increasingly entailing local geographic scales and encouraging the mobilization and organization of territorial actors given local conditions and resources. Lebanon is a country facing frequent uncertainty with recent economic and social difficulties. Its popular cuisine may play a key role in its development and that of its rural space. In fact, that cuisine incorporates a traditional cultural practice called "Mouneh" which consists of preserved pantry foods, historically used to ensure household nutrition. Today, rural food cooperatives are engaging in that practice using agricultural produce from local farmers and are employing women. Despite strong internal and external challenges, they remain attractive actors as their principles of collective benefit, participation and democracy form a strong link with sustainable development goals. This study transversally analyzes the status of food cooperatives in a major agricultural region in Lebanon, the Bekaa valley. Findings mainly quantified size and production and provided a mapped representation of the spatial dependencies on local farmers versus urban markets for trade. With 75% women members and firm reputation in authenticity, food cooperatives in the Bekaa specifically and Lebanon generally are also extensively supported by donors but are being labeled as donor-dependent. Yet, cooperatives are localized in a largely agricultural territory with sufficient evidence of differentiation that could potentially be valorized. Hence, with optimal framing, regulation and networking of cooperatives, one can assume a protection of culinary heritage is possible with scalable contribution to food security and needed local development given major recent setbacks.
    Keywords: Cooperatives,Lebanon,Bekaa valley,Sustainable development goals
    Date: 2020
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hal:journl:hal-03137540&r=all
  3. By: Stavros, Drakopoulos
    Abstract: Since the emergence of the classical school, the scientific ideal of physical sciences has been a constant influence on economic theory and method. Its influence is still present in contemporary neoclassical economics. Similarly to the case of physics, classical economists were very open in incorporating psychological elements in the economic discourse. This openness towards psychology continued with prominent Marginalist economists, like Jevons and Edgeworth, who were eager to draw from psychological ideas found in earlier authors. In the first decades of the 20th century, a major conceptual change in economics took place which is also known as the Paretian turn. This conceptual change, initiated mainly by Vilfredo Pareto, and completed, in the first decades of the 20th century, by J. Hicks, R. Allen and P. Samuelson, attempted to remove all psychological notions from economic theory. The legacy of the Paretian turn can still be identified in the significant reluctance of the contemporary orthodox economic theory to incorporate the findings of the new behavioral economics, a field with a discernable psychological bent. This chapter argues that the history of the relation of those two subjects to economics can lead to some potentially useful observations concerning the nature of contemporary neoclassical economics. It will also be maintained that the relationship of neoclassical economics to physics ultimately constrained its interaction with psychology.
    Keywords: Economic Methodology; Economics and Psychology; Economics and Physics; History of Economic Thought
    JEL: B0 B40
    Date: 2021–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:106597&r=all
  4. By: Shrouq Al Maghlouth (King Faisal University, Hofuf, 31982, Al Ahsa, Saudi Arabia Author-2-Name: Author-2-Workplace-Name: Author-3-Name: Author-3-Workplace-Name: Author-4-Name: Author-4-Workplace-Name: Author-5-Name: Author-5-Workplace-Name: Author-6-Name: Author-6-Workplace-Name: Author-7-Name: Author-7-Workplace-Name: Author-8-Name: Author-8-Workplace-Name:)
    Abstract: Objective - This paper examines empirically the discourse on social change as represented in gender-related posts on English blogs written by Saudi bloggers. Slightly more than a decade ago, Saudi women were allowed and encouraged by the government to work in unconventional work environments (outside the fields of education and health care); this stirred controversy across the country. Methodology/Technique - This analysis is based on an understanding of discourse as both shaping and being shaped by social and cognitive contexts. In so doing, it approaches the data from a socio-cognitive perspective with a focus on the mental models underlying the discursive representations at hand. The adopted methodology is based on metaphor analysis due to the inherently cognitive nature of metaphors. Consequently, an eclectic approach combining insights from conceptual metaphor theory and critical theory analysis is used. Finding - Data analysis reveals two main findings. First, change is constructed cognitively as challenging and demanding for both women aspiring to work in unconventional professions and their supporters on authoritative and non-authoritative levels. This, however, clashes with the second finding, as in these blogs women are metaphorically constructed in an objectifying and victimizing manner. Novelty - Such a mismatch calls for a careful examination of some gender constraining cognitive constructions as they are, surprisingly, constructed and reproduced even within discourse attempting to empower women. Type of Paper - Empirical
    Keywords: Social Change; Critical Discourse Analysis; Women's Empowerment; Metaphor Analysis
    JEL: M14 Q56
    Date: 2021–03–31
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:gtr:gatrjs:gjbssr579&r=all
  5. By: Michael A. Nelson; Rajeev K. Goel
    Abstract: This paper adds to our understanding of the causes of income inequality across nations by examining the influence of different aspects of gender equality or female empowerment. Whereas the economics of income inequality has been an area of active academic inquiry, the role of gender equality has largely been ignored. Are there positive spillovers from gender equality onto income equality? The answer to this question, using data for nearly 150 nations over the years 1985-2019, is in the affirmative. Specifically, nations with a history of women’s suffrage, greater representation of women in the government, lower fertility rates, and better overall gender equality experienced lower income inequality, ceteris paribus. These results are largely supported in considerations of cross-section versus pooled data, simultaneity issues, and the measurement of income inequality. The spillovers from some dimensions of gender equality are found to be sensitive to the existing prevalence of income inequality. Policymakers ignoring the payoffs from gender empowerment on income distribution might be underinvesting in initiatives to empower women.
    Keywords: income inequality, gender inequality, suffrage, fertility, women in parliament, colonialism, GINI coefficient, government, quantile regression
    JEL: D31 D63 E25 I32 J16 O15
    Date: 2021
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ces:ceswps:_8949&r=all
  6. By: Moehring, Katja (University of Mannheim); Reifenscheid, Maximiliane; Weiland, Andreas
    Abstract: This paper evaluates gender inequality in employment risks during the first and the second wave of the COVID-19 pandemic in Germany. We use individual-level panel data collected weekly between 20 March and 9 July 2020, and again in January 2021, to examine the risks of short-time work, job loss and unpaid furlough, as well as having to work on-site by means of growth curve modelling. The results reveal gender inequality in employment risks and gendered use of governmental support schemes. During the early phase of the pandemic, women had a higher probability of being temporarily exempted from work, but a lower probability of being in short-time work and receiving the associated state benefits. Compared to men, women also continuously had a higher probability of working on-site rather that from home. Consequently, women’s employment during the pandemic is more polarized between job loss or working on-site with the associated infection risk. Gender inequalities are rooted in the long-term gendered dualization of the German labour market with the low-wage sector and marginal employment being female dominated. The results call for close monitoring of long-term gendered effects of the pandemic recession and an adjustment of governmental crisis measures to the requirements of the female workforce.
    Date: 2021–03–18
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:osf:socarx:tzma5&r=all
  7. By: Ann L. Owen; Judit Temesvary; Andrew Wei
    Abstract: We examine the effect of the social networks of bank directors on board gender diversity and compensation using a unique, newly compiled dataset over the 1999-2018 period. We find that within-board social networks are extensive, but there are significant differences in the size and gender composition of social networks of male vs female bank directors. We also find that samegender networks play an important role in determining the gender composition of bank boards. Finally, we show that those connected to male directors receive higher compensation, but we find no evidence that connections to female directors are influential in determining pay and bonuses.
    Keywords: Bank boards; Social networks; Gender; Gender diversity
    JEL: G21 G34 J16
    Date: 2021–03–22
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:fip:fedgfe:2021-21&r=all
  8. By: Elena Grinza; Francesco Devicienti; Mariacristina Rossi; Davide Vannoni
    Abstract: The attitudes of people about how paid and unpaid work should be divided between the members of a couple (gender role attitudes) determine the economic and social outcomes of women to a great extent. It is thus important to understand how the gender role attitudes of people are formed and evolve. In this paper, we concentrate on one of the most path breaking events in life: becoming a parent. Using rich longitudinal data from the UK and fixed-effects regressions, we first show that, in general, entry into parenthood significantly shifts the gender role attitudes of women toward more traditional positions, but leaves men unaffected. We then show that prenatal attitudes are crucial in driving the change in attitudes of new parents. We find a substantial traditionalization of gender role attitudes for new parents who had more progressive prenatal attitudes, with no distinction between the sexes. Conversely, no significant attitude change is observed for parents with more conservative prenatal attitudes after entering into parenthood. Novel moderating analyses also show that the traditionalization of attitudes for progressive individuals, after they become parents, becomes substantially stronger as the experience of (and exposure to) traditional postnatal arrangements in the division of paid and unpaid work increases.
    Keywords: Gender role attitudes, entry into parenthood, gender identity, cognitive dissonance, gendered institutions and gender stereotypes, Understanding Society data set.
    JEL: J16 J13 D02
    Date: 2020
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cca:wpaper:635&r=all
  9. By: Muriel Dal Pont Legrand (Université Côte d'Azur, CNRS, GREDEG, France)
    Abstract: This paper analyses how the macro agent-based literature which developed intensively during the last decades, analyses the issue of financial instability. This paper focuses its attention on two specific researchers’ communities which, within this new paradigm, specifically emphasize this question. We examine their common analytical foundations, how they have been influenced by anterior research programs, and we distinguish their modeling strategies and how these distinct strategies led them to follow somewhat different objectives.
    Keywords: Macro agent-based models, financial instability, microeconomic foundations, CATS, K&S, Minsky, Leijonhufvud, Stiglitz
    JEL: B22 B31 B41 E32
    Date: 2021–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:gre:wpaper:2021-14&r=all
  10. By: Louis-Gaëtan Giraudet (ENPC - École des Ponts ParisTech); Bénédicte Apouey (PSE - Paris School of Economics - ENPC - École des Ponts ParisTech - ENS Paris - École normale supérieure - Paris - PSL - Université Paris sciences et lettres - UP1 - Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne - CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique - EHESS - École des hautes études en sciences sociales - INRAE - Institut National de Recherche pour l’Agriculture, l’Alimentation et l’Environnement); Hazem Arab (UP1 - Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne); Simon Baeckelandt (Université de Lille); Philippe Begout; Nicolas Berghmans (IDDRI - Institut du Développement Durable et des Relations Internationales - Institut d'Études Politiques [IEP] - Paris); Nathalie Blanc (CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique); Jean-Yves Boulin (Université Paris Dauphine-PSL - PSL - Université Paris sciences et lettres, IRISSO - Institut de Recherche Interdisciplinaire en Sciences Sociales - Université Paris Dauphine-PSL - PSL - Université Paris sciences et lettres - INRAE - Institut National de Recherche pour l’Agriculture, l’Alimentation et l’Environnement); Eric Buge (Assemblée Nationale); Dimitri Courant (UNIL - Université de Lausanne); Amy Dahan (CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique); Adrien Fabre (ETH Zürich - Eidgenössische Technische Hochschule - Swiss Federal Institute of Technology in Zürich [Zürich]); Jean-Michel Fourniau (Université Gustave Eiffel); Maxime Gaborit (Université Saint-Louis - Bruxelles); Laurence Granchamp (CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique); Hélène Guillemot (CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique); Laurent Jeanpierre (UP1 - Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne); Hélène Landemore (Yale University [New Haven]); Jean-François Laslier (PSE - Paris School of Economics - ENPC - École des Ponts ParisTech - ENS Paris - École normale supérieure - Paris - PSL - Université Paris sciences et lettres - UP1 - Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne - CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique - EHESS - École des hautes études en sciences sociales - INRAE - Institut National de Recherche pour l’Agriculture, l’Alimentation et l’Environnement); Antonin Macé (PSE - Paris School of Economics - ENPC - École des Ponts ParisTech - ENS Paris - École normale supérieure - Paris - PSL - Université Paris sciences et lettres - UP1 - Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne - CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique - EHESS - École des hautes études en sciences sociales - INRAE - Institut National de Recherche pour l’Agriculture, l’Alimentation et l’Environnement); Claire Mellier- Wilson (Cardiff University); Sylvain Mounier; Théophile Pénigaud (ENS Lyon - École normale supérieure - Lyon); Ana Povoas (ULB - Université libre de Bruxelles); Christiane Rafidinarivo (UR - Université de La Réunion); Bernard Reber (CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique); Romane Rozencwajg (UP8 - Université Paris 8 Vincennes-Saint-Denis); Philippe Stamenkovic; Selma Tilikete (UP8 - Université Paris 8 Vincennes-Saint-Denis); Solène Tournus (CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique)
    Abstract: Citizens' assemblies are gaining traction as a means to address complex issues such as climate change. We report on our unique experience in observing debates among the 150 members of the French Citizens' Convention for Climate and highlight its implications for both climate action and the science of deliberation. We note that France took an original approach characterized by (i) sustained interactions between citizens and the steering board; (ii) a significant input from technical and legal experts; (iii) and a strong emphasis on creating consensus, leaving little room for expressing dissent. This resulted in the citizens approving 149 measures, 146 of which President Macron committed to follow up on. Yet as implementation is now under discussion, the promise that measures would pass "unfiltered" appears increasingly questioned.
    Date: 2021–01–26
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hal:wpaper:hal-03119539&r=all
  11. By: May, Ann Mari
    Abstract: Book Review of “The Routledge Handbook of the History of Women’s Economic Thought” by Kirsten Madden and Robert W. Dimand
    Date: 2020–09–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:osf:osfxxx:wtg4b&r=all
  12. By: Kevin Genna (AMSE - Aix-Marseille Sciences Economiques - EHESS - École des hautes études en sciences sociales - AMU - Aix Marseille Université - ECM - École Centrale de Marseille - CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique); Christian Ghiglino (Department of Economics, University of Essex - University of Essex); Kazuo Nishimura (RIEB, Kobe University - Kobe University); Alain Venditti (AMSE - Aix-Marseille Sciences Economiques - EHESS - École des hautes études en sciences sociales - AMU - Aix Marseille Université - ECM - École Centrale de Marseille - CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique, EDHEC - EDHEC Business School)
    Abstract: How will structural change unfold beyond the rise of services? Motivated by the observed dynamics within the service sector we propose a model of structural change in which productivity is endogenous and output is produced with two intermediate substitutable capital goods. In the progressive sector the accumulation of knowledge leads to an unbounded increase in TFP, as sector becoming asymptotically dominant. We are then able to recover the increasing shares of workers, the increasing real and nominal shares of the output observed in progressive service and IT sectors in the US. Interestingly, the economy follows a growth path converging to a particular level of wealth that depends on the initial price of capital and knowledge. As a consequence, countries with the same fundamentals but lower initial wealth will be characterized by lower asymptotic wealth.
    Keywords: two-sector model,technological knowledge,constant elasticity of substitution,non-balanced endogenous growth,structural change,Kaldor and Kuznets facts
    Date: 2021–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hal:wpaper:halshs-03164854&r=all
  13. By: Andrea La Nauze
    Abstract: I test whether economic incentives dampen peer effects in public-good settings. I study how a visible and subsidized contribution to a public good (installing solar panels) affects peer contributions that are neither subsidized nor visible (electing green power). Exploiting spatial variation in the feasibility of installing solar panels, I find that panels increase voluntary purchases of green power by neighbors. However, using sharp changes in government incentives over time, I find that the magnitude of the spillover depends on the level of subsidies to solar. The results support the hypothesis that signals drive peer responses to visible public-good contributions and that economic incentives blur those signals.
    Keywords: motivation, public goods contribution, solar panels, green energy, environmental public goods
    Date: 2021
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ces:ceswps:_8940&r=all
  14. By: Celso Brunetti; Benjamin Dennis; Dylan Gates; Diana Hancock; David Ignell; Elizabeth K. Kiser; Gurubala Kotta; Anna Kovner; Richard J. Rosen; Nicholas K. Tabor
    Abstract: This Note describes how risks arising from climate change may affect financial stability. We describe how climate-change related risks may emerge either as shocks to the financial system or as financial system vulnerabilities that could amplify the effects of these or other shocks.
    Date: 2021–03–19
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:fip:fedgfn:2021-03-19-3&r=all
  15. By: Matteo Laffi; Ron Boschma;
    Abstract: The aim of the paper is to shed light on the role played by regional knowledge bases in Industry 3.0 in fostering new technologies in Industry 4.0 in European regions (NUTS3) over the period 1991-2015. We find that 4.0 technologies appear to be quite related to 3.0 technologies, with some heterogeneity among different technology fields. The paper investigates the geographical implications. We find that the probability of developing Industry 4.0 technologies is higher in regions that are specialised in Industry 3.0 technologies. However, other types of knowledge bases also sustain regional diversification in Industry 4.0 technologies.
    Keywords: Fourth Industrial Revolution, Industry 4.0, regional innovation, patents, knowledge space, relatedness, EU regions
    JEL: B52 O33 R11
    Date: 2021–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:egu:wpaper:2112&r=all
  16. By: Priddat, Birger P.
    Abstract: Angst, Sorge und Tod sind die verdeckten Existenzial der Pandemie. Für die Angstund die Sorge sind die Gastwirte und Händler zuständig, deren Existenzenökonomisch bedroht sind. Und die Künstler. Für den Tod sind die Krankenhäuserzuständig, die in hohem Einsatz doch aber kaum die Todeszahlen mindern können(März 2021 ca. 60.000). Aber darüber kommuniziert die Gesellschaft nicht (nur diebetroffenen Angehörigen, die keinen letzten Kontakt mit ihren Sterbendenaufnehmen dürfen). Der Gesellschaft fehlt für all das die Sprache. Dabei gibt eseine Philosophie (Heideggers), die diese unbedachten Tatbestände denken kann.Das geht wahrlich nicht in kritikferner Übernahme, aber lässt eine 'Ökonomie derSorge' formulieren. Zu Beginn der Pandemie ließ sich eine 'Ökonomie der Sorge'ausbilden, die jetzt, am Beginn der dritten Welle wieder akut wird. Der Textanalysiert die Pandemie als existentielles Phänomen.
    Keywords: Angst,Sorge,Tod,Daseinsfürsorge,Pandemie,Ökonomie der Sorge
    JEL: A19 B59
    Date: 2021
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:zbw:cuswps:68&r=all

This nep-hme issue is ©2021 by Carlo D’Ippoliti. It is provided as is without any express or implied warranty. It may be freely redistributed in whole or in part for any purpose. If distributed in part, please include this notice.
General information on the NEP project can be found at http://nep.repec.org. For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese at <director@nep.repec.org>. Put “NEP” in the subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.