New Economics Papers
on Business, Economic and Financial History
Issue of 2008‒02‒02
fifteen papers chosen by



  1. Change and continuity: the development of joint stock banking in the early nineteenth century By Lucy Newton
  2. Weetman Pearson in Mexico and the Emergence of a British Oil Major, 1901-1919 By Andrew Godley; Lisa Bud Frierman; Judith Wale
  3. Bond Markets and Banks in Inter-War Japan By Makoto Kasuya
  4. Gender Roles and Technological Progress By Stefania Albanesi; Claudia Olivetti
  5. Democratizing Luxury and the Contentious 'Invention of the Technological Chicken' in Britain By Andrew Godley
  6. Political Economy Origins of Financial Markets in Europe and Asia By Svetlana Andrianova; Panicos Demetriades; Chenggang Xu
  7. The Chicken, the Factory Farm and the Supermarket: the Emergence of the Modern Poultry Industry in Britain By Andrew Godley; Bridget Williams
  8. Embourgeoisement' before affluence? Suburbanisation and the social filtering of working-class communities in interwar Britain By Peter Scott
  9. Regional and National Industrial Policies in Italy, 1950s-1993. Where Did the Subsidies Flow?" By Anna Spadavecchia
  10. War and endogenous democracy. By Ticchi, Davide; Vindigni, Andrea
  11. Peace, War and International Security: Economic Theories By J Paul Dunne; Fanny Coulomb
  12. Mr Drage, Mr Everyman, and the creation of a mass market for domestic furniture in interwar Britain By Peter Scott
  13. Trade and Empire By Kris James Mitchener; Marc Weidenmier
  14. Institutional Adaptability and Economic Development: The Property Rights Revolution in Britain, 1700 to 1830 By Gary Richardson; Dan Bogart
  15. The value of Sainsbury's sales data in assessing the impact of self-service methods on food retailing in postwar Britain By Bridget Williams

  1. By: Lucy Newton (Department of Management, University of Reading)
    Date: 2007
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:rdg:emxxdp:em-dp2007-40&r=his
  2. By: Andrew Godley (Department of Management, University of Reading); Lisa Bud Frierman (Visiting research fellow at the Centre for International Business History, University of Reading); Judith Wale (Visiting research fellow at the Centre for International Business History, University of Reading)
    Abstract: British overseas investment was one of the most powerful forces contributing to rapid global integration before World War 1. Approaching half of this total was in the form of foreign direct investment, as British entrepreneurs increasingly located their activities away from the mature domestic economy to faster growing, less-developed regions. Weetman Pearson was one of the most successful of all Britain’s overseasbased entrepreneurs of the period. Using original financial records, the paper shows how the Pearson group of companies became one of Britain’s most valuable industrial enterprises by 1919 having diversified from international contracting into the Mexican oil industry from 1901. The Pearson group highlights how British entrepreneurs were technically competent in managing large, complex infrastructure projects, able to navigate their way through various political systems, and adept at turning to whichever organisational form best suited their business interests; characteristics far removed from the outdated stereotype of the incompetent Late Victorian entrepreneur
    Date: 2007
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:rdg:emxxdp:em-dp2007-42&r=his
  3. By: Makoto Kasuya
    Abstract: Issues of bonds increased in inter-war Japan, the main investors in bonds being banks because demand for loans declined in this period. Banks that were more tolerant of risks (that is, whose capital ratio was higher) made a larger amount of loans, which were riskier than bonds. While national bonds were traded actively in secondary markets, local bonds, corporate bonds, and bank debentures were not traded actively during this period. After the formation of cartels of banks and securities firms for bond underwriting and trading during the Great Depression, bond trading in secondary markets diminished, except for national bonds.
    Keywords: Japanese Banks, bond markets, inter-war period, the Great Depression, national bonds, corporate bonds, cartels, capital.
    Date: 2007–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cep:stiisp:/2007/521&r=his
  4. By: Stefania Albanesi (Department of Economics, Columbia University); Claudia Olivetti (Boston University - Department of Economics)
    Abstract: Until the early decades of the 20th century, women spent more than 60% of their prime-age years either pregnant or nursing. Since then, the introduction of infant formula reduced women's comparative advantage in infant care, by providing an effective breast milk substitute. In addition, improved medical knowledge and obstetric practices reduced the time cost associated with women's reproductive role. We explore the hypothesis that these developments enabled married women to increase their participation in the labor force, thus providing the incentive to invest in market skills, which in turn reduced their earnings differential with respect to men. We document these changes and develop a quantitative model that aims to capture their impact. Our results suggest that progress in medical technologies related to motherhood was essential to generate a significant rise in the participation of married women between 1920 and 1950, in particular those with young children.
    JEL: J13 J16 J2 J22 N3 O3
    Date: 2007
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:clu:wpaper:0607-12&r=his
  5. By: Andrew Godley (Department of Management, University of Reading)
    Abstract: In 1950 poultry was a rare luxury in Britain, only one per cent of the total meat consumption. But over the next thirty years chicken consumption grew at the remarkable (compound) rate of 10 per cent per annum, while the overall consumption of meat remained stagnant from the 1950s to the 1980s. By then poultry had become the single most important source of meat, with a quarter of the total share of the market, replacing former favourites like beef, mutton and bacon in the British diet. This transformation was made possible by the emergence of intensive rearing in poultry farming. This was a dramatic change in production, dependent on technological innovations across several otherwise unrelated sectors: in pharmaceuticals and feedstuffs production, in refrigeration, slaughtering and packaging. The widespread distribution of cheap chicken led to its mass adoption throughout the country. But such a transformation in meat eating habits was not without its controversies. Contemporary concerns emerged from the late 1950s over the possible long term dangers to human health from the technological transformation inherent in intensive rearing regimes. The paper emphasises that it was the leading retailers, in particular J. Sainsbury, who acted as a key intermediary in this contested market, reconciling consumer uncertainty by attaching their own reputation to product quality, and then furthermore by intervening in the quality standards employed in its supply chain.
    Date: 2007–12
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:rdg:emxxdp:em-dp2007-54&r=his
  6. By: Svetlana Andrianova; Panicos Demetriades; Chenggang Xu
    Abstract: This paper contributes to the finance-growth literature by examining the political economy origins of some of the most successful financial markets in Europe and Asia. It provides historical evidence from London, Amsterdam and Hong Kong that highlights the essential role played by the government sector in kick-starting financial development. We show that the emergence of financial systems did not occur through laissez-faire approaches and that secure property rights alone were not sufficient for financial development. In the cases of London and Amsterdam, governments created large trade monopolies which were responsible for all the major financial innovations of the time. In the case of Hong Kong, where the financial developmentmodel was bank-based, large banking monopolies with close links to the state were created. We argue that the three examples are not special cases and the role of government in the early stages of financial development has been widespread world-wide.
    Date: 2008–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:edb:cedidp:08-01&r=his
  7. By: Andrew Godley (Department of Management, University of Reading); Bridget Williams
    Date: 2007
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:rdg:emxxdp:em-dp2007-50&r=his
  8. By: Peter Scott (Centre for International Business History, University of Reading)
    Date: 2007
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:rdg:emxxdp:em-dp2007-41&r=his
  9. By: Anna Spadavecchia (Department of Management, University of Reading)
    Abstract: This paper compares the magnitude and distribution of regional subsidies to Southern industry to those of subsidies available in the country as a whole through the national industrial policy. The comparison highlights the fact that from the second half of the 1970s, industry located in the most prosperous region of Italy, the North-West, was the main beneficiary of subsidised credit. These findings refine our understanding of the regional policy for Southern Italy and the reasons for its limited achievements. Moreover, the redirection of subsidies away from the South cast doubts on the extent of the Italian government’s commitment to its programme of regional development.
    Keywords: Regional policy; Industrial policy; Regional pattern of government spending
    JEL: R58 H50 N94
    Date: 2007
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:rdg:emxxdp:em-dp2007-48&r=his
  10. By: Ticchi, Davide; Vindigni, Andrea
    Abstract: Many episodes of extension of franchise in the 19th and especially in the 20th century occurred during or in the aftermath of major wars. Motivated by this fact, we offer a theory of political transitions which focuses on the impact of international conflicts on domestic political institutions. We argue that mass-armies, which appeared in Europe after the French Revolution, are an effective military organization only if the conscripted citizens are willing to put effort in fighting wars, which in turn depends on the economic incentives that are provided to them. The need to provide such incentives, implies that an oligarchy adopting a mass-army may voluntarily decide to promise some amount of income redistribution to its citizens, conditionally on satisfactory performance as soldiers. When the elite cannot credibly commit to provide an incentive-compatible redistribution, they may cope with the moral hazard problem of the citizens-soldiers only by relinquishing political power to them through the extension of franchise. This is because democracy always implements a highly redistributive fiscal policy, which makes fighting hard incentive-compatible for the citizens-soldiers. We show that a transition to democracy is more likely to occur when the external threat faced by an incumbent oligarchy is in some sense intermediate. A very high external threat allows the elite to make credible commitments of future income redistribution in favor of the citizens, while a limited external threat makes optimal for the elite not making any (economic or political) concession to the masses. Some historical evidence consistent with our theory is also provided.
    Keywords: Autocracy, Democracy, Wars, Redistribution
    JEL: D72 D74 H56 N40 P16
    Date: 2007–12
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:uca:ucapdv:97&r=his
  11. By: J Paul Dunne (School of Economics, University of the West of England, Bristol); Fanny Coulomb (University Pierre Mendes, Grenoble.)
    Abstract: This paper considers the economic theories that are relevant for the study of peace war and international security . It presents different levels of generality, starting with the big questions of international security, which are usually the domain of international relations, before moving to general economic theoretical perspectives and then focusing on some specific developments in economics and security. More specifically it reviews the economics of security, distinguishing neoclassical theories, Keynesian and institutional, Marxist, and monopoly capital, before discussing the issues involved in the debate between the schools of thought. The economics of conflict is then considered, starting with the approach economists have taken –mainly neoclassical, before considering more general political economy perspectives.
    Keywords: Economics; Peace; war; security;
    JEL: H56 B20
    Date: 2008–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:uwe:wpaper:0803&r=his
  12. By: Peter Scott (Centre for International Business History, University of Reading)
    Abstract: This paper examines strategies used by durable goods retailers to create a mass market in interwar Britain, via a case-study of domestic furniture. Interwar demand for new furniture witnessed particularly rapid growth - mainly owing to the extension of the market to lower-income groups. A number of innovative national retailers eveloped liberal HP facilities to bring furniture within the economic reach of these groups, while sophisticated national advertising campaigns were used to both legitimise buying furniture on HP and project furnishing by this means as key to achieving the type of aspriational lifestyles being promulgated in the popular media.
    Date: 2007
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:rdg:emxxdp:em-dp2007-44&r=his
  13. By: Kris James Mitchener; Marc Weidenmier
    Abstract: Although many modern studies find large and significant effects of prior colonial status on bilateral trade, there is very little empirical research that has focused on the contemporaneous impact of empire on trade. We employ a new database of over 21,000 bilateral trade observations during the Age of High Imperialism, 1870-1913, to quantitatively assess the effect of empire on trade. Our augmented gravity model shows that belonging to an empire roughly doubled trade relative to those countries that were not part of an empire. The positive impact that empire exerts on trade does not appear to be sensitive to whether the metropole was Britain, France, Germany, Spain, or the United States or to the inclusion of other institutional factors such as being on the gold standard. In addition, we examine some of the channels through which colonial status impacted bilateral trade flows. The empirical analysis suggests that empires increased trade by lowering transactions costs and by establishing trade policies that promoted trade within empires. In particular, the use of a common language, the establishment of currency unions, the monetizing of recently acquired colonies, preferential trade arrangements, and customs unions help to account for the observed increase in trade associated with empire.
    JEL: F15 F33 N20 N23 N40
    Date: 2008–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:13765&r=his
  14. By: Gary Richardson; Dan Bogart
    Abstract: Adaptable property-rights institutions, we argue, foster economic development. The British example illustrates this point. Around 1700, Parliament established a forum where rights to land and resources could be reorganized. This venue enabled landholders and communities to take advantage of economic opportunities that could not be accommodated by the inflexible rights regime inherited from the past. In this essay, historical evidence, archival data, and statistical analysis demonstrate that Parliament increased the number of acts reorganizing property rights in response to increases in the public's demand for such acts. This evidence corroborates a cornerstone of our hypothesis.
    JEL: H1 K0 K1 N0 N43 P1 P10 P14 P16 P20 P26 P48
    Date: 2008–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:13757&r=his
  15. By: Bridget Williams
    Date: 2007
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:rdg:emxxdp:em-dp2007-49&r=his

General information on the NEP project can be found at https://nep.repec.org. For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese at <director@nep.repec.org>. Put “NEP” in the subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.