nep-gth New Economics Papers
on Game Theory
Issue of 2022‒08‒22
nineteen papers chosen by
Sylvain Béal
Université de Franche-Comté

  1. Simultaneous Contests with Equal Sharing Allocation of Prizes: Computational Complexity and Price of Anarchy By Edith Elkind; Abheek Ghosh; Paul W. Goldberg
  2. Withholding Verifiable Information By Kun Zhang
  3. Splitting games over finite sets By Frédéric Koessler; Marie Laclau; Jérôme Renault; Tristan Tomala
  4. Measuring strategic-uncertainty attitudes By Lisa Bruttel; Muhammed Bulutay; Camille Cornand; Frank Heinemann; Adam Zylbersztejn
  5. Iterative Monotone Comparative Statics By Lukasz Balbus; Wojciech Olszewski; Kevin Reffett; Lukasz Wozny
  6. The Inverse Problem of Linear Quadratic Differential Games: When is a Profile of Control Strategies Nash? By Yunhan Huang; Tao Zhang; Quanyan Zhu
  7. Alternative Forms of Buyer Power in a Vertical Duopoly: Implications for profits and consumer welfare By Aditya Bhattacharjea; Srishti Gupta
  8. Homo economicus to model human behavior is ethically doubtful and mathematically inconsistent By M. Lunkenheimer; A. Kracklauer; G. Klinkova; M. Grabinski
  9. Playing Divide-and-Choose Given Uncertain Preferences By Jamie Tucker-Foltz; Richard Zeckhauser
  10. Dynamic Budget Throttling in Repeated Second-Price Auctions By Zhaohua Chen; Chang Wang; Qian Wang; Yuqi Pan; Zhuming Shi; Chuyue Tang; Zheng Cai; Yukun Ren; Zhihua Zhu; Xiaotie Deng
  11. Endogenous market structures, product liability, and the scope of product differentiation By Eric Langlais; Andreea Cosnita-Langlais
  12. Government Intervention in Catastrophe Insurance Markets: A Reinforcement Learning Approach By Menna Hassan; Nourhan Sakr; Arthur Charpentier
  13. The Winner-Take-All Dilemma By Kazuya Kikuchi; Yukio Koriyama
  14. Markov Chain Approaches to Payoff Optimization in the Self-Organizing Network Coloring Game By Zeyi Chen
  15. A core-selecting auction for portfolio's packages By Lamprirni Zarpala; Dimitris Voliotis
  16. A Game-theoretic Model of the Consumer Behavior Under Pay-What-You-Want Pricing Strategy By Vahid Ashrafimoghari; Jordan W. Suchow
  17. Analogy-Based Expectation Equilibrium and Related Concepts:Theory, Applications, and Beyond By Philippe Jehiel
  18. Morally Monotonic Choice in Public Good Games By James C. Cox; Vjollca Sadiraj; Susan Xu Tang
  19. Cooperation in Social Dilemmas with Correlated Noisy Payoffs: Theory and Experimental Evidence By Evans, Alecia; Sesmero, Juan

  1. By: Edith Elkind; Abheek Ghosh; Paul W. Goldberg
    Abstract: We study a general scenario of simultaneous contests that allocate prizes based on equal sharing: each contest awards its prize to all players who satisfy some contest-specific criterion, and the value of this prize to a winner decreases as the number of winners increases. The players produce outputs for a set of activities, and the winning criteria of the contests are based on these outputs. We consider two variations of the model: (i) players have costs for producing outputs; (ii) players do not have costs but have generalized budget constraints. We observe that these games are exact potential games and hence always have a pure-strategy Nash equilibrium. The price of anarchy is $2$ for the budget model, but can be unbounded for the cost model. Our main results are for the computational complexity of these games. We prove that for general versions of the model exactly or approximately computing a best response is NP-hard. For natural restricted versions where best response is easy to compute, we show that finding a pure-strategy Nash equilibrium is PLS-complete, and finding a mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium is (PPAD$\cap$PLS)-complete. On the other hand, an approximate pure-strategy Nash equilibrium can be found in pseudo-polynomial time. These games are a strict but natural subclass of explicit congestion games, but they still have the same equilibrium hardness results.
    Date: 2022–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:arx:papers:2207.08151&r=
  2. By: Kun Zhang
    Abstract: I study a class of verifiable disclosure games where the sender's payoff is state independent and the receiver's optimal action only depends on the posterior mean of the state. The sender's messages are verifiable in the sense that every message must contain the true state. I identify necessary and sufficient conditions for a particular information design outcome to be achieved by an equilibrium of the verifiable disclosure game, and give sufficient conditions on model primitives under which the sender does not benefit from commitment power. These results help in characterizing the sender's preferred equilibria and her equilibrium payoff set in a class of verifiable disclosure games. I apply these insights to study influencing voters and selling with quality disclosure.
    Date: 2022–06
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:arx:papers:2206.09918&r=
  3. By: Frédéric Koessler (PSE - Paris School of Economics - UP1 - Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne - ENS-PSL - École normale supérieure - Paris - PSL - Université Paris sciences et lettres - EHESS - École des hautes études en sciences sociales - ENPC - École des Ponts ParisTech - CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique - INRAE - Institut National de Recherche pour l’Agriculture, l’Alimentation et l’Environnement, PJSE - Paris Jourdan Sciences Economiques - UP1 - Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne - ENS-PSL - École normale supérieure - Paris - PSL - Université Paris sciences et lettres - EHESS - École des hautes études en sciences sociales - ENPC - École des Ponts ParisTech - CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique - INRAE - Institut National de Recherche pour l’Agriculture, l’Alimentation et l’Environnement); Marie Laclau (HEC Paris - Ecole des Hautes Etudes Commerciales, GREGHEC - Groupement de Recherche et d'Etudes en Gestion - HEC Paris - Ecole des Hautes Etudes Commerciales - CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique); Jérôme Renault (TSE - Toulouse School of Economics - UT1 - Université Toulouse 1 Capitole - Université Fédérale Toulouse Midi-Pyrénées - EHESS - École des hautes études en sciences sociales - CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique - INRAE - Institut National de Recherche pour l’Agriculture, l’Alimentation et l’Environnement); Tristan Tomala (HEC Paris - Ecole des Hautes Etudes Commerciales, GREGHEC - Groupement de Recherche et d'Etudes en Gestion - HEC Paris - Ecole des Hautes Etudes Commerciales - CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique)
    Abstract: This paper studies zero-sum splitting games with finite sets of states. Players dynamically choose a pair of martingales {pt,qt}t, in order to control a terminal payoff u(p∞,q∞). A first part introduces the notion of "Mertens–Zamir transform" of a real-valued matrix and use it to approximate the solution of the Mertens–Zamir system for continuous functions on the square [0,1]2. A second part considers the general case of finite splitting games with arbitrary correspondences containing the Dirac mass on the current state: building on Laraki and Renault (Math Oper Res 45:1237–1257, 2020), we show that the value exists by constructing non Markovian ε-optimal strategies and we characterize it as the unique concave-convex function satisfying two new conditions.
    Keywords: Splitting games,Mertens-Zamir system,Repeated games with incomplete information,Bayesian persuasion,Information design
    Date: 2022
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hal:journl:halshs-03672222&r=
  4. By: Lisa Bruttel (Universität Potsdam, Department for Economics and Social Sciences, Chair for Economics Markets, Competition, and Institutions - August-Bebel-Str. 89 - 14482 Potsdam, Germany); Muhammed Bulutay (Technische Universität Berlin, Chair of Macroeconomics, H 52 - Straße des 17. Juni 135 - 10 623 Berlin, Germany); Camille Cornand (Univ Lyon, CNRS, GATE UMR 5824, F-69130 Ecully, France); Frank Heinemann (Technische Universität Berlin, Chair of Macroeconomics, H 52 - Straße des 17. Juni 135 - 10 623 Berlin, Germany); Adam Zylbersztejn (Univ Lyon, Université Lumière Lyon 2, GATE UMR 5824, F-69130 Ecully, France; research fellow at Vistula University Warsaw (AFiBV), Warsaw, Poland)
    Abstract: Strategic uncertainty is the uncertainty that players face with respect to the purposeful behavior of other players in an interactive decision situation. Our paper develops a new method for measuring strategic-uncertainty attitudes and distinguishing them from risk and ambiguity attitudes. We vary the source of uncertainty (whether strategic or not) across conditions in a ceteris paribus manner. We elicit certainty equivalents of participating in two strategic 2x2 games (a stag-hunt and a market-entry game) as well as certainty equivalents of related lotteries that yield the same possible payoffs with exogenously given probabilities (risk) and lotteries with unknown probabilities (ambiguity). We provide a structural model of uncertainty attitudes that allows us to measure a preference for or an aversion against the source of uncertainty, as well as optimism or pessimism regarding the desired outcome. We document systematic attitudes towards strategic uncertainty that vary across contexts. Under strategic complementarity [substitutability], the majority of participants tend to be pessimistic [optimistic] regarding the desired outcome. However, preferences for the source of uncertainty are distributed around zero.
    Keywords: risk attitudes, ambiguity attitudes, strategic-uncertainty attitudes, stag-hunt game, market-entry game
    JEL: C72 C91 C92 D81
    Date: 2022
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:gat:wpaper:2211&r=
  5. By: Lukasz Balbus; Wojciech Olszewski; Kevin Reffett; Lukasz Wozny
    Abstract: For an increasing upper order hemi-continuous correspondence F selfmapping sigma-complete lattice A, we first provide tight fixed-point bounds for sufficiently large iterations on F starting from any initial point a in A. We use this result for conducting iterative fixed-point comparative statics, and then apply our results to monotone games and economies. For games of strategic complementarities, we improve the correspondence principle based results of Echenique (2002) by allowing for divergent learning processes, unstable fixed points, equilibrium indeterminacies, and unordered perturbations. We also apply our results to the comparative statics of stationary equilibria in large economies and the set of recursive equilibria in macroeconomic models with indeterminacies.
    Keywords: comparative statics; comparative dynamics; adaptive learning; monotone iterations; games with strategic complementarities
    JEL: C62 C65 C72
    Date: 2022–02
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:sgh:kaewps:2022072&r=
  6. By: Yunhan Huang; Tao Zhang; Quanyan Zhu
    Abstract: This paper aims to formulate and study the inverse problem of non-cooperative linear quadratic games: Given a profile of control strategies, find cost parameters for which this profile of control strategies is Nash. We formulate the problem as a leader-followers problem, where a leader aims to implant a desired profile of control strategies among selfish players. In this paper, we leverage frequency-domain techniques to develop a necessary and sufficient condition on the existence of cost parameters for a given profile of stabilizing control strategies to be Nash under a given linear system. The necessary and sufficient condition includes the circle criterion for each player and a rank condition related to the transfer function of each player. The condition provides an analytical method to check the existence of such cost parameters, while previous studies need to solve a convex feasibility problem numerically to answer the same question. We develop an identity in frequency-domain representation to characterize the cost parameters, which we refer to as the Kalman equation. The Kalman equation reduces redundancy in the time-domain analysis that involves solving a convex feasibility problem. Using the Kalman equation, we also show the leader can enforce the same Nash profile by applying penalties on the shared state instead of penalizing the player for other players' actions to avoid the impression of unfairness.
    Date: 2022–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:arx:papers:2207.05303&r=
  7. By: Aditya Bhattacharjea (Department of Economics, Delhi School of Economics); Srishti Gupta (Department of Economics, Delhi School of Economics)
    Abstract: We derive several variations of a model in which two upstream firms supply a differentiated product to two downstream firms under exclusive contracts of different kinds. We first derive a benchmark model with upstream first-mover pricing. We then compare its outcomes with four other types of vertical arrangements representing different modes of exploiting buyer power: downstream first mover pricing; Nash bargaining, alternatively with linear and two-part tariffs; and vertical integration. In each case, we show how the equilibrium values of wholesale and retail prices as well as downstream firms’ profits are affected by changes in the exogenous parameters (degree of product differentiation, bargaining power, and production costs). We evaluate the various vertical regimes from the perspective of downstream firms’ profits as well as consumer welfare, and show how more powerful downstream firms can benefit consumers by exercising “countervailing power” against upstream firms. Key Words: Buyer power, Bertrand duopoly, Vertical contracts, Nash bargaining, Vertical integration. JEL Codes: D43, L13, L22
    Date: 2022–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cde:cdewps:326&r=
  8. By: M. Lunkenheimer; A. Kracklauer; G. Klinkova; M. Grabinski
    Abstract: In many models in economics or business a dominantly self-interested homo economicus is assumed. Unfortunately (or fortunately), humans are in general not homines economici as e.g. the ultimatum game shows. This leads to the fact that all these models are at least doubtful. Moreover, economists started to set a quantitative value for the feeling of social justice, altruism, or envy and the like to execute utilitarian calculation. Besides being ethically doubtful, it delivers an explanation in hindsight with little predicting power. We use examples from game theory to show its arbitrariness. It is even possible that a stable Nash equilibrium can be calculated while it does not exist at all, due to the wide differences in human values. Finally, we show that assigned numbers for envy or altruism and the like do not build a field (in a mathematical sense). As there is no homomorphism to real numbers or a subset of it, any calculation is generally invalid or arbitrary. There is no (easy) way to fix the problem. One has to go back to ethical concepts like the categorical imperative or use at most semi quantitative approaches like considering knaves and knights. Mathematically one can only speculate whether e.g. surreal numbers can make ethics calculable.
    Date: 2022–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:arx:papers:2207.02902&r=
  9. By: Jamie Tucker-Foltz; Richard Zeckhauser
    Abstract: We study the classic divide-and-choose method for equitably allocating divisible goods between two players who are rational, self-interested Bayesian agents. The players have additive private values for the goods. The prior distributions on those values are independent and common knowledge. We characterize the structure of optimal divisions in the divide-and-choose game and show how to efficiently compute equilibria. We identify several striking differences between optimal strategies in the cases of known versus unknown preferences. Most notably, the divider has a compelling "diversification" incentive in creating the chooser's two options. This incentive, hereto unnoticed, leads to multiple goods being divided at equilibrium, quite contrary to the divider's optimal strategy when preferences are known. In many contexts, such as buy-and-sell provisions between partners, or in judging fairness, it is important to assess the relative expected utilities of the divider and chooser. Those utilities, we show, depend on the players' uncertainties about each other's values, the number of goods being divided, and whether the divider can offer multiple alternative divisions. We prove that, when values are independently and identically distributed across players and goods, the chooser is strictly better off for a small number of goods, while the divider is strictly better off for a large number of goods.
    Date: 2022–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:arx:papers:2207.03076&r=
  10. By: Zhaohua Chen; Chang Wang; Qian Wang; Yuqi Pan; Zhuming Shi; Chuyue Tang; Zheng Cai; Yukun Ren; Zhihua Zhu; Xiaotie Deng
    Abstract: Throttling is one of the most popular budget control methods in today's online advertising markets. When a budget-constrained advertiser employs throttling, she can choose whether or not to participate in an auction after the advertising platform recommends a bid. This paper focuses on the dynamic budget throttling process in repeated second-price auctions from a theoretical view. An essential feature of the underlying problem is that the advertiser does not know the distribution of the highest competing bid upon entering the market. To model the difficulty of eliminating such uncertainty, we consider two different information structures. The advertiser could obtain the highest competing bid in each round with full-information feedback. Meanwhile, with partial information feedback, the advertiser could only have access to the highest competing bid in the auctions she participates in. We propose the OGD-CB algorithm, which involves simultaneous distribution learning and revenue optimization. In both settings, we demonstrate that this algorithm guarantees an $O(\sqrt{T\log T})$ regret with probability $1 - O(1/T)$ relative to the fluid adaptive throttling benchmark. By proving a lower bound of $\Omega(\sqrt{T})$ on the minimal regret for even the hindsight optimum, we establish the near optimality of our algorithm. Finally, we compare the fluid optimum of throttling to that of pacing, another widely adopted budget control method. The numerical relationship of these benchmarks sheds new light on the understanding of different online algorithms for revenue maximization under budget constraints.
    Date: 2022–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:arx:papers:2207.04690&r=
  11. By: Eric Langlais; Andreea Cosnita-Langlais
    Abstract: The paper considers how product liability may shape firm size, product specification choices and market structure. We introduce a spatial Cournot duopoly on the linear market, where firms make an initial decision of product differentiation, then invest in precaution, before competing in quantity. Our main results are fourfold; 1) with full coverage of the market by the duopoly, there exist two equilibria (in pure strategies): central agglomeration (which is stable for low liability costs), and dispersion (which is stable for not too large liabiliy costs); 2) for larger liability costs, a mixed market structure duopoly/monopoly sustains a unique equilibrium with product differentiation; 3) this equilibrium enables a scope of differentiation higher (smaller) than the full duopoly (the social optimum); 4) the impact of liability costs on firms size and profits is complex, since it depends on the impact on both product differentiation and market structure. Finally, we show that consumer surplus and social welfare are both higher under the mixed market structure than under the full duopoly in an equilibrium with product differentiation.
    Keywords: horizontal differentiation, Cournot competition, spatial model, endogenous market structures, product liability, strict liability, negligence
    JEL: L41 K21 D82
    Date: 2022
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:drm:wpaper:2022-18&r=
  12. By: Menna Hassan; Nourhan Sakr; Arthur Charpentier
    Abstract: This paper designs a sequential repeated game of a micro-founded society with three types of agents: individuals, insurers, and a government. Nascent to economics literature, we use Reinforcement Learning (RL), closely related to multi-armed bandit problems, to learn the welfare impact of a set of proposed policy interventions per $1 spent on them. The paper rigorously discusses the desirability of the proposed interventions by comparing them against each other on a case-by-case basis. The paper provides a framework for algorithmic policy evaluation using calibrated theoretical models which can assist in feasibility studies.
    Date: 2022–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:arx:papers:2207.01010&r=
  13. By: Kazuya Kikuchi; Yukio Koriyama
    Abstract: We consider collective decision making when the society consists of groups endowed with voting weights. Each group chooses an internal rule that specifies the allocation of its weight to the alternatives as a function of its members' preferences. Under fairly general conditions, we show that the winner-take-all rule is a dominant strategy, while the equilibrium is Pareto dominated, highlighting the dilemma structure between optimality for each group and for the whole society. We also develop a technique for asymptotic analysis and show Pareto dominance of the proportional rule. Our numerical computation for the US Electoral College verifies its sensibility.
    Date: 2022–06
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:arx:papers:2206.09574&r=
  14. By: Zeyi Chen
    Abstract: The model of Network Coloring Game (NCG) is used to simulate conflict resolving and consensus reaching procedures in social science. In this work, we adopted some Markov Chain Techniques into the investigation of NCG. Firstly, with no less than $\Delta + 2$ colors provided, we proposed and proved that the conflict resolving time has its expectation to be $O(\log n)$ and the variance $O((\log n)^2)$, thus is $O_p(\log n)$, where $n$ is the number of vertices and $\Delta$ is the maximum degree of the network. This was done by introducing an absorbing Markov Chain into NCG. Secondly, we developed algorithms to reduce the network in post-conflict-resolution adjustments when a Borda rule is applied among players. Markov Chain Monte Carlo methods were employed to estimate both local and global optimal payoffs. Supporting experimental results were given to illustrate the corresponding procedures.
    Date: 2022–06
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:arx:papers:2206.09153&r=
  15. By: Lamprirni Zarpala; Dimitris Voliotis
    Abstract: We introduce the \enquote{local-global} approach for a divisible portfolio and perform an equilibrium analysis for two variants of core-selecting auctions. Our main novelty is extending the Nearest-VCG pricing rule in a dynamic two-round setup, mitigating bidders' free-riding incentives and further reducing the sellers' costs. The two-round setup admits an information-revelation mechanism that may offset the \enquote{winner's curse}, and it is in accord with the existing iterative procedure of combinatorial auctions. With portfolio trading becoming an increasingly important part of investment strategies, our mechanism contributes to increasing interest in portfolio auction protocols.
    Date: 2022–06
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:arx:papers:2206.11516&r=
  16. By: Vahid Ashrafimoghari; Jordan W. Suchow
    Abstract: In a digital age where companies face rapid changes in technology, consumer trends, and business environments, there is a critical need for continual revision of the business model in response to disruptive innovation. A pillar of innovation in business practices is the adoption of novel pricing schemes, such as Pay-What-You-Want (PWYW). In this paper, we employed game theory and behavioral economics to model consumers' behavior in response to a PWYW pricing strategy where there is an information asymmetry between the consumer and supplier. In an effort to minimize the information asymmetry, we incorporated the supplier's cost and the consumer's reference prices as two parameters that might influence the consumer's payment decision. Our model shows that consumers' behavior varies depending on the available information. As a result, when an external reference point is provided, the consumer tends to pay higher amounts to follow the social herd or respect her self-image. However, the external reference price can also decrease her demand when, in the interest of fairness, she forgoes the purchase because the amount she is willing to pay is less that what she recognizes to be an unrecoverable cost to the supplier.
    Date: 2022–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:arx:papers:2207.08923&r=
  17. By: Philippe Jehiel (PSE - Paris School of Economics - UP1 - Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne - ENS-PSL - École normale supérieure - Paris - PSL - Université Paris sciences et lettres - EHESS - École des hautes études en sciences sociales - ENPC - École des Ponts ParisTech - CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique - INRAE - Institut National de Recherche pour l’Agriculture, l’Alimentation et l’Environnement, PJSE - Paris Jourdan Sciences Economiques - UP1 - Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne - ENS-PSL - École normale supérieure - Paris - PSL - Université Paris sciences et lettres - EHESS - École des hautes études en sciences sociales - ENPC - École des Ponts ParisTech - CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique - INRAE - Institut National de Recherche pour l’Agriculture, l’Alimentation et l’Environnement, UCL - University College of London [London])
    Abstract: A unified definition of analogy-based expectation equilibrium (ABEE) for strategic environments involving multiple stages and private information is presented. Various alternative interpretations of the concept are proposed as well as a discussion of how to use ABEE in practice. A variety of applications including two new ones related to speculative trading and personnel economics is reviewed. A discussion of a number of alternative equilibrium concepts follows emphasizing the links and differences with ABEE. Finally, a discussion of possible next steps in particular related to the endogeneization of analogy partitions is proposed.
    Keywords: Analogy-Based Expectation,bounded rationality,limited learning
    Date: 2022–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hal:psewpa:halshs-03735680&r=
  18. By: James C. Cox; Vjollca Sadiraj; Susan Xu Tang
    Abstract: Consequentialist rational choice theory, including models of (unconditional) social preferences, is challenged by decades of robust data from payoff-equivalent public good games with provision or appropriation as well as by robust data showing contributions to public goods, funded by lump-sum taxation, do not crowd out voluntary contributions on a one-for-one basis. This paper offers an extension of rational choice theory that incorporates observable moral reference points. This morally monotonic choice theory is consistent with robust data in the literature and has idiosyncratic features that motivate new experimental designs that introduce nonbinding quotas on appropriations or floors on provisions. Data, from three previous experiments and our new experiment, favor moral monotonicity over alternative theoretical models including rational choice theory, prominent belief-based models of kindness, and popular reference-dependent models with loss aversion.
    Keywords: choice theory, public goods, experiment, payoff equivalence, non-binding contractions, moral reference points, belief-based psychological models, reference-dependent choices
    JEL: C91 D03 H41
    Date: 2022–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:exc:wpaper:2022-01&r=
  19. By: Evans, Alecia; Sesmero, Juan
    Keywords: Institutional and Behavioral Economics
    Date: 2022–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ags:aaea21:322804&r=

This nep-gth issue is ©2022 by Sylvain Béal. It is provided as is without any express or implied warranty. It may be freely redistributed in whole or in part for any purpose. If distributed in part, please include this notice.
General information on the NEP project can be found at http://nep.repec.org. For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese at <director@nep.repec.org>. Put “NEP” in the subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.