nep-gth New Economics Papers
on Game Theory
Issue of 2013‒09‒24
thirteen papers chosen by
Laszlo A. Koczy
Hungarian Academy of Sciences and Obuda University

  1. Consistency and its Converse for Roommate Markets By Bettina Klaus
  2. Price of Anarchy in Sequencing Situations and the Impossibility to Coordinate By Herbert Hamers; Flip Klijn; Marco Slikker
  3. On the Convergence to the Nash bargaining solution for action-dependent bargaining protocols By BRITZ, Volker; HERINGS, Jean-Jacques; PREDTETCHINSKI, Arkadi
  4. Assignment Games with Externalities By Gudmundsson, Jens; Habis, Helga
  5. Estimation of Discrete Games with Correlated Types By Haiqing Xu
  6. A Zero-Sum Stochastic Game with Compact Action Sets and no Asymptotic Value. By Vigeral, Guillaume
  7. Play it Again: Partner Choice, Reputation Building and Learning in Restarting, Finitely-Repeated Dilemma Games By Kenju Kamei; Louis Putterman
  8. Aggregate Oligopoly Games with Entry By Anderson, Simon P; Erkal, Nisvan; Piccinin, Daniel
  9. Bayes Correlated Equilibrium and the Comparison of Information Structures By Dirk Bergemann; Stephen Morris
  10. Dynamic Countervailing Power under Public and Private Monitoring By Bhaskar, Venkataraman
  11. Do Sellers Offer Menus of Contracts to Separate Buyer Types? An Experimental Test of Adverse Selection Theory By Hoppe, Eva I; Schmitz, Patrick W
  12. Competing for Consumer Inattention By de Clippel, Geoffroy; Eliaz, Kfir; Rozen, Kareen
  13. Constructing Social Division to Support Cooperation: Theory and Evidence from Nepal By Choy, James

  1. By: Bettina Klaus
    Abstract: For marriage markets with equal numbers of men and women and where all men find all women acceptable and all women find all men acceptable, Sasaki and Toda (1992) characterize the core by anonymity, Pareto optimality, consistency, and converse consistency. In a recent paper, Nizamogullari and Özkal-Sanver (2012) generalize this result to the full domain of marriage markets by adding individual rationality and by replacing anonymity with gender fairness. We generalize both results by characterizing the core on the domain of no odd rings roommate markets by individual rationality, anonymity, Pareto optimality, consistency, and converse consistency. We also prove that extending this characterization to the domain of solvable roommate markets is not possible.
    Keywords: Converse Consistency; Core; Marriage and Roommate Markets
    JEL: C78 D63
    Date: 2013–09
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:lau:crdeep:13.12&r=gth
  2. By: Herbert Hamers; Flip Klijn; Marco Slikker
    Abstract: Scheduling jobs of decentralized decision makers that are in competition will usually lead to cost inefficiencies. This cost inefficiency is studied using the Price of Anarchy (PoA), i.e., the ratio between the worst Nash equilibrium cost and the cost attained at the centralized optimum. First, we provide a tight upperbound for the PoA that depends on the number of machines involved. Second, we show that it is impossible to design a scheduled-based coordinating mechanism in which a Nash equilibrium enforces the centralized or first best optimum. Finally, by simulations we illustrate that on average the PoA is relatively small with respect to the established tight upperbound.
    Keywords: sequencing situations, outsourcing, first best solution, game theory, price of anarchy, coordinating mechanism
    JEL: C72 D82
    Date: 2013–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:bge:wpaper:709&r=gth
  3. By: BRITZ, Volker (ETH Zürich, Switzerland); HERINGS, Jean-Jacques (Maastricht University, The Netherlands; Université catholique de Louvain, CORE, B-1348 Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium.); PREDTETCHINSKI, Arkadi (Maastricht University, The Netherlands)
    Abstract: We consider a non–cooperative multilateral bargaining game and study an action–dependent bargaining protocol, that is, the probability with which a player becomes the proposer in a round of bargaining depends on the identity of the player who previously rejected. An important example is the frequently studied rejector–becomes–proposer protocol. We focus on subgame perfect equilibria in stationary strategies which are shown to exist and to be efficient. Equilibrium proposals do not depend on the probability to propose conditional on the rejection by another player, though equilibrium acceptance sets do depend on these probabilities. Next we consider the limit, as the bargaining friction vanishes. In case no player has a positive probability to propose conditional on his rejection, each player receives his utopia payoff conditional on being recognized and equilibrium payoffs are in general Pareto inefficient. Otherwise, equilibrium proposals of all players converge to a weighted Nash Bargaining Solution, where the weights are determined by the probability to propose conditional on a rejection.
    Keywords: strategic bargaining, subgame perfect equilibrium, stationary strategies, Nash bargaining solution
    JEL: C78
    Date: 2013–09–11
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cor:louvco:2013044&r=gth
  4. By: Gudmundsson, Jens (Department of Economics, Lund University); Habis, Helga (Department of Economics, Lund University)
    Abstract: We introduce externalities into a two-sided, one-to-one assignment game by letting the values generated by pairs depend on the behavior of the other agents. Extending the notion of blocking to this setup is not straightforward; a pair has to take into account the possible reaction of the residual agents to be able to assess the value it could achieve. We define blocking in a rather general way that allows for many behavioral considerations or beliefs. The main result of the paper is that a stable outcome in an assignment game with externalities always exists if and only if all pairs are pessimistic regarding the others' reaction following a deviation. The relationship of stability and optimality is also discussed, as is the structure of the set of stable outcomes.
    Keywords: Two-sided matching; assignment game; externalities; stability
    JEL: C71 C78 D62
    Date: 2013–08–27
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hhs:lunewp:2013_027&r=gth
  5. By: Haiqing Xu (Department of Economics, Texas University)
    Abstract: This paper focuses on the identification and estimation of static games of incomplete information with correlated types. Instead of making the (conditional) independence assumption on players' types to simplify the equilibria set, I establish a method that allows to identify subsets of the space of covariates (i.e. publicly observed state variables in payoff functions), for which there exists a unique Bayesian Nash Equilibrium (BNE) and the equilibrium strategies are monotone functions. The unique monotone pure strategy BNE can be characterized in a simple manner, based on which I propose an estimation procedure exploiting the information contained in the subset of the covariate space, and establish the consistency and the limiting distribution of the estimator.
    Keywords: Incomplete Information Game, Monotone Pure Strategy BNE, Maximum Likelihood Estimation
    JEL: C35 C62 C72
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:tex:wpaper:130909&r=gth
  6. By: Vigeral, Guillaume
    Abstract: We give an example of a zero-sum stochastic game with four states, compact action sets for each player, and continuous payoff and transition functions, such that the discounted value does not converge as the discount factor tends to 0, and the value of the n-stage game does not converge as n goes to infinity.
    Keywords: Compact action sets; Uniform value; Asymptotic behavior; Zero sum stochastic games;
    JEL: C73
    Date: 2013
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ner:dauphi:urn:hdl:123456789/10880&r=gth
  7. By: Kenju Kamei; Louis Putterman
    Abstract: Previous research has shown that opportunities for two-sided partner choice in finitely repeated social dilemma games can promote cooperation through a combination of sorting and opportunistic signaling, with late period defections by selfish players causing an end-game decline. How such experience would affect play of subsequent finitely-repeated games remains unclear. In each of six treatments that vary the cooperation premium and the informational basis for reputation formation, we let sets of subjects play sequences of finitely-repeated voluntary contribution games to study the competing forces of (a) learning about the benefits of reputation, and (b) learning about backward unraveling. We find, inter alia, that with a high cooperation premium and good information, investment in reputation grows across sets of finitely-repeated games.
    Keywords: cooperation, reputation, voluntary contribution, public goods, sorting, endogenous grouping, group formation, experiment
    Date: 2013
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:bro:econwp:2013-8&r=gth
  8. By: Anderson, Simon P; Erkal, Nisvan; Piccinin, Daniel
    Abstract: We use cumulative reaction functions to compare long-run market structures in aggregative oligopoly games. We first compile an IO toolkit for aggregative games. We show strong neutrality properties across market structures. The aggregator stays the same, despite changes in the number of firms and their actions. The IIA property of demands (CES and logit) implies that consumer surplus depends on the aggregator alone, and that the Bertrand pricing game is aggregative. We link together the following results: merging parties' profits fall but consumer surplus is unchanged, Stackelberg leadership raises welfare, monopolistic competition is the market structure with the highest surplus.
    Keywords: aggregative games; contests; Cournot; entry; IIA property; leadership; Logit/CES; mergers; monopolistic competition; oligopoly theory; R&D; strategic substitutes and complements
    JEL: D43 L13
    Date: 2013–06
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cpr:ceprdp:9511&r=gth
  9. By: Dirk Bergemann; Stephen Morris
    Date: 2013–09–19
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cla:levarc:786969000000000725&r=gth
  10. By: Bhaskar, Venkataraman
    Abstract: We examine buyer strategic power in the model of dynamic Bertrand-Edgeworth competition. Two sellers with a limited inventory sell to a single buyer, who has a consumption opportunity in each period. The market power of the sellers is offset by the strategic power of the buyer. By not consuming in any period, the buyer can destroy a unit of demand, thereby intensifying future price competition. If transactions are publicly observed, we find that that a strategic buyer can do significantly better than non-strategic buyers; strategic power may also give rise to inefficiencies. However, if an agent only perfectly observes those transactions in which he is directly involved, and imperfectly observes other transactions, the strategic power of the buyer is reduced, and in some cases, may be completely eliminated. This highlights the sharp discontinuity between the equilibrium outcomes between perfect and imperfect monitoring.
    Keywords: Bertrand-Edgeworth competition; dynamic games; imperfect monitoring; strategic buyer
    JEL: D43 D92
    Date: 2013–06
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cpr:ceprdp:9526&r=gth
  11. By: Hoppe, Eva I; Schmitz, Patrick W
    Abstract: In the basic adverse selection model, a seller makes a contract offer to a privately informed buyer. A fundamental hypothesis of incentive theory is that the seller may want to offer a menu of contracts to separate the buyer types. In the good state of nature, total surplus is not different from the symmetric information benchmark, while in the bad state, private information may be welfare-reducing. We have conducted a laboratory experiment with 954 participants to test these hypotheses. While the results largely corroborate the theoretical predictions, we also find that private information may be welfare-enhancing in the good state.
    Keywords: Incentive theory; Laboratory experiment; Mechanism design; Private information
    JEL: C72 C92 D82 D86
    Date: 2013–06
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cpr:ceprdp:9510&r=gth
  12. By: de Clippel, Geoffroy; Eliaz, Kfir; Rozen, Kareen
    Abstract: Consumers purchase multiple types of goods and services, but may be able to examine only a limited number of markets for the best price. We propose a simple model which captures these features, conveying some new insights. A firm's price can deflect or draw attention to its market, and consequently, limited attention introduces a new dimension of competition across markets. We fully characterize the resulting equilibrium, and show that the presence of partially attentive consumers improves consumer welfare as a whole. When consumers are less attentive, they are more likely to miss the best offer in each market; but the enhanced cross-market competition decreases average price paid, as leading firms try to stay under the consumers' radar.
    Keywords: Limited attention
    JEL: C72 D43
    Date: 2013–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cpr:ceprdp:9553&r=gth
  13. By: Choy, James (Department of Economics, University of Warwick)
    Abstract: Many societies are divided into multiple smaller groups. The defining feature of these groups is that certain kinds of interaction are more likely to take place within a group than across groups. I build a model in which group divisions are enforced through a reputational penalty for interacting with members of different groups. Agents who interact with members of different groups find that they can support lower levels of cooperation in the future. The model explains why agents may be punished by the other members of their group for interacting with members of different groups and why agents are punished for interacting with members of some groups but not others. I test the empirical implication that there should be less cooperation among members of groups that make up a larger percentage of their communities. I discuss the origin and possible future of social division. JEL classification: Cooperation ; Caste ; Social Institution JEL codes: C7 ; O12 ; O17
    Date: 2013
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:wrk:warwec:1011&r=gth

This nep-gth issue is ©2013 by Laszlo A. Koczy. It is provided as is without any express or implied warranty. It may be freely redistributed in whole or in part for any purpose. If distributed in part, please include this notice.
General information on the NEP project can be found at http://nep.repec.org. For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese at <director@nep.repec.org>. Put “NEP” in the subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.