nep-gth New Economics Papers
on Game Theory
Issue of 2012‒09‒16
seventeen papers chosen by
Laszlo A. Koczy
Hungarian Academy of Sciences and Obuda University

  1. On the Convergence to Nash Bargaining Solution for Endogenous Bargaining Protocols By Herings P. Jean-Jacques; Britz Volker; Predtetchinski Arkadi
  2. Continuous-time Stochastic Games By Abraham Neyman
  3. Spectrum Value for Coalitional Games By Mikel Alvarez-Mozos; Ziv Hellman; Eyal Winter
  4. The Strategic Impact of Higher-Order Beliefs By Yi-Chun Chen; Alfredo Di Tillio; Eduardo Faingold; Siyang Xiong
  5. Transaction costs can encourage Coasean bargaining By Alex Robson
  6. Time as a Medium of Reward in Three Social Preference Experiments By Noussair, C.N.; Stoop, J.T.R.
  7. Continuous Values of Market Games are Conic By Omer Edhan
  8. An experimental study of mixed strategy equilibria in simultaneous price-quantity games By Daniel Cracau; Benjamin Franz
  9. Continuous-Time Stochastic Games of Fixed Duration By Yehuda (John) Levy
  10. Representations Of Positive Projections On Lipschitz Vector By Omer Edhan
  11. Values of Exact Market Games By Omer Edhan
  12. On Sharing the Benefits of Communication By Athanasiou Efthymios; Dey Santanu; Valletta Giacomo
  13. Pairwise Mutual Knowledge and Correlated Rationalizability By Tsakas Elias
  14. Gens una sumus? – Or Does Political Ideology Affect Experts’ Aesthetic Judgement of Chess Games By Björn Frank; Stefan Krabel
  15. On the Measurement of Success and Satisfaction By René van den Brink; Frank Steffen
  16. Alliances in the Shadow of Conflict By Changxia Ke; Kai A. Konrad; Florian Morath
  17. Peacekeeping: a Strategic Approach By Max Blouin

  1. By: Herings P. Jean-Jacques; Britz Volker; Predtetchinski Arkadi (METEOR)
    Abstract: We consider non-cooperative multilateral bargaining games with endogenous bargaining protocols.Under an endogenous protocol, the probability with which a player becomes the proposer in a roundof bargaining depends on the identity of the player who previously rejected. An important exampleis the frequently studied rejector-becomes-proposer protocol. We focus on subgame perfectequilibria in stationary strategies which are shown to exist and to be efficient. Equilibriumproposals do not depend on the probability to proposeconditional on the rejection by another player, though equilibrium acceptance sets do depend onthese probabilities. Next we consider the limit, as the bargaining friction vanishes. In case noplayer has a positive probability to propose conditional on his rejection, each player receiveshis utopia payoff conditional on being recognized and equilibrium payoffs are in general Paretoinefficient. Otherwise, equilibrium proposals of all players converge to a weighted NashBargaining Solution, where the weights are determined by the probability to propose conditional ona rejection.
    Keywords: microeconomics ;
    Date: 2012
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:dgr:umamet:2012030&r=gth
  2. By: Abraham Neyman
    Abstract: Every continuous-time stochastic game with finitely many states and actions has a uniform and limiting-average equilibrium payoff.
    Date: 2012–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:huj:dispap:dp616&r=gth
  3. By: Mikel Alvarez-Mozos; Ziv Hellman; Eyal Winter
    Abstract: Assuming a `spectrum' or ordering on the players of a coalitional game, as in a political spectrum in a parliamentary situation, we consider a variation of the Shapley value in which coalitions may only be formed if they are connected with respect to the spectrum. This results in a naturally asymmetric power index in which positioning along the spectrum is critical. We present both a characterisation of this value by means of properties and combinatoric formulae for calculating it. In simple majority games, the greatest power accrues to `moderate' players who are located neither at the extremes of the spectrum nor in its centre. In supermajority games, power increasingly accrues towards the extremes, and in unaninimity games all power is held by the players at the extreme of the spectrum.
    Date: 2012–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:huj:dispap:dp618&r=gth
  4. By: Yi-Chun Chen (Dept. of Economics, National University of Singapore); Alfredo Di Tillio (IGIR and Dept. of Economics, Universita Luigi Bocconi); Eduardo Faingold (Cowles Foundation, Yale University); Siyang Xiong (Dept. of Economics, Rice University)
    Abstract: Previous research has established that the predictions made by game theory about strategic behavior in incomplete information games are quite sensitive to the assumptions made about the players' infinite hierarchies of beliefs. We evaluate the severity of this robustness problem by characterizing conditions on the primitives of the model -- the players’ hierarchies of beliefs -- for the strategic behavior of a given Harsanyi type to be approximated by the strategic behavior of (a sequence of) perturbed types. This amounts to providing characterizations of the strategic topologies of Dekel, Fudenberg, and Morris (2006) in terms of beliefs. We apply our characterizations to a variety of questions concerning robustness to perturbations of higher-order beliefs, including genericity of common priors, and the connections between robustness of strategic behavior and the notion of common p-belief of Monderer and Samet (1989).
    Keywords: Games with incomplete information, Rationalizability, Higher-order beliefs, Robustness
    JEL: C70 C72
    Date: 2012–09
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cwl:cwldpp:1875&r=gth
  5. By: Alex Robson
    Keywords: Coase Theory, externalities, transaction costs, cooperatives games
    JEL: D23 K00 C71 C78 D62
    Date: 2012–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:gri:epaper:economics:201208&r=gth
  6. By: Noussair, C.N.; Stoop, J.T.R. (Tilburg University, Center for Economic Research)
    Abstract: Abstract: We report results from three well-known experimental paradigms, where we use time, rather than money, as the salient component of subjects’ incentives. The three experiments, commonly employed to study social preferences, are the dictator game, the ultimatum game and the trust game. All subjects in a session earn the same participation fee, but their choices affect the time at which they are permitted to leave the laboratory, with decisions typically associated with greater own payoff translating into an earlier departure. The modal proposal in both the dictator and ultimatum games is an equal split of the waiting time. In the trust game, there is substantial trust and reciprocity. Overall, social preferences are evident in time allocation decisions. Received laboratory results from dictator, ultimatum, and trust games are robust to the change in reward medium, though there is some suggestive evidence that decisions are even more prosocial with respect to time than money.
    Keywords: dictator game;ultimatum game;trust game;time.
    JEL: C70 C91 D63 D64
    Date: 2012
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:dgr:kubcen:2012068&r=gth
  7. By: Omer Edhan
    Abstract: We prove that every continuous value on a space of vector measure market games $Q$, containing the space of nonatomic measures $NA$, has the \textit{conic property}, i.e., if a game $v\in Q$ coincides with a nonatomic measure $\nu$ on a conical diagonal neighborhood then $\varphi(v)=\nu$. We deduce that every continuous value on the linear space $\mathcal M$, spanned by all vector measure market games, is determined by its values on $\mathcal{LM}$ - the space of vector measure market games which are Lipschitz functions of the measures.
    Date: 2012–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:huj:dispap:dp623&r=gth
  8. By: Daniel Cracau (Faculty of Economics and Management, Otto-von-Guericke University Magdeburg); Benjamin Franz (Mathematical Institute, University of Oxford)
    Abstract: We study oligopoly games with firms competing in prices and quantities at the same time. We systematically compare our experimental results to the theoretical predictions using the mixed strategy equilibria for linear demand functions. For the duopoly game, we observe that the mixed strategy equilibrium predicts average outcomes better than Cournot and Bertrand do. Subjects' price choices are mainly between marginal cost and monopoly level but do not follow the equilibrium distribution. Although average prices and profits are above theoretical values, we do not observe a high level of collusion as expected in the literature. By comparing simulations based on the mixed strategy equilibrium to our experimental outcomes, we conclude that in this game price setting can be explained by strategic reaction to preceding round results. In contrast to the equilibrium prediction, we observe a decrease in prices and negative average profits for the triopoly game.
    Keywords: Price-Quantity Competition; Mixed Strategy Equilibria; Experimental Economics; Learning Direction Theory
    JEL: D43 L11
    Date: 2012–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:mag:wpaper:120017&r=gth
  9. By: Yehuda (John) Levy
    Abstract: We study non-zero-sum continuous-time stochastic games, also known as continuous-time Markov games, of fixed duration. We concentrate on Markovian strategies. We show by way of example that equilibria need not exist in Markovian strategies, but they always exist in Markovian public-signal correlated strategies. To do so, we develop criteria for a strategy profile to be an equilibrium via differential inclusions, both directly and also by modeling continuous-time stochastic as differential games and using the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman equations. We also give an interpretation of equilibria in mixed strategies in continuous-time, and show that approximate equilibria always exist.
    Date: 2012–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:huj:dispap:dp617&r=gth
  10. By: Omer Edhan
    Abstract: Among the single-valued solution concepts studied in cooperative game theory and economics, those which are also positive projections play an important role. The value, semivalues, and quasivalues of a cooperative game are several examples of solution concepts which are positive projections. These solution concepts are known to have many important applications in economics. In many applications the specific positive projection discussed is represented as an expectation of marginal contributions of agents to ``random" coalitions. Usually these representations are used to characterize positive projections obeying certain additional axioms. It is thus of interest to study the representation theory of positive projections and its relation with some common axioms. We study positive projections defined over certain spaces of nonatomic Lipschitz vector measure games. To this end, we develop a general notion of ``calculus" for such games, which in a manner extends the notion of the Radon-Nykodim derivative for measures. We prove several representation results for positive projections, which essentially state that the image of a game under the action of a positive projection can be represented as an averaging of its derivative w.r.t. some vector measure. We then introduce a specific calculus for the space $\mathcal{CON}$ generated by concave, monotonically nondecreasing, and Lipschitz continuous functions of finitely many nonatomic probability measures. We study in detail the properties of the resulting representations of positive projections on $\mathcal{CON}$ and especially those of values on $\mathcal{CON}$. The latter results are of great importance in various applications in economics.
    Date: 2012–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:huj:dispap:dp624&r=gth
  11. By: Omer Edhan
    Abstract: We prove that a single-valued solution of perfectly competitive TU economies underling nonatomic exact market games is uniquely determined as the Mertens value by four plausible value-related axioms. Since the Mertens value is always a core element, this result provides an axiomatization of the Mertens value as a core-selection. Previous works in this direction assumed the economies to be either di erentiable (e.g., Dubey and Neyman [9]) or of uniform nite-type (e.g., Haimanko [14]). Our work does not assume that, thus it contributes to the axiomatic study of payo s in perfectly competitive economies (or values of their derived market games) in general. In fact, this is the rst contribution in this direction.
    Date: 2012–09
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:huj:dispap:dp627&r=gth
  12. By: Athanasiou Efthymios; Dey Santanu; Valletta Giacomo (METEOR)
    Abstract: We put forward a model of private goods with externalities. Agents derive benefit fromcommunicating with each other. In order to communicate they need to have a language in common.Learning languages is costly. In this setting no individually rational and feasible Grovesmechanism exists. We characterize the best-in-class feasible Groves mechanism and thebest-in-class individually rational Groves mechanism.
    Keywords: public economics ;
    Date: 2012
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:dgr:umamet:2012016&r=gth
  13. By: Tsakas Elias (METEOR)
    Abstract: We provide epistemic conditions for correlated rationalizability, which are considerably weakerthan the ones by Zambrano (2008). More specifically, we simultaneously replace mutual knowledge ofrationality and mutual knowledge of the event that every player deems possible only strategyprofiles that belong to the support of her actual conjecture, with strictly weaker epistemicconditions of pairwise mutual knowledge of these events.Moreover, we show that our epistemic foundation for correlated rationalizability does not implymutual knowledge of rationality.
    Keywords: microeconomics ;
    Date: 2012
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:dgr:umamet:2012031&r=gth
  14. By: Björn Frank (University of Kassel); Stefan Krabel (University of Kassel)
    Abstract: This paper presents evidence on biased voting by jurors from the Warsaw Pact countries who ranked high-level chess games. The roots of this bias are probably ideological, as there were no formal benefits for biased voting. Furthermore, this bias is observed only for jurors from Eastern countries, not for those from the West (NATO), and most interestingly, it disappears after the collapse of the Warsaw pact in 1989.
    Date: 2012
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:mar:magkse:201237&r=gth
  15. By: René van den Brink (VU University Amsterdam); Frank Steffen (The University of Liverpool Management School)
    Abstract: The main purpose of the present paper is to disentangle the mix-up of the notions of success and satisfaction which is prevailing in the voting power literature. We demonstrate that both notions are conceptually distinct, and discuss their relationship and measurement. We show that satisfaction contains success as one component, and that both coincide under the canonical set-up of a simultaneous decision-making mechanism as it is predominant in the voting power literature. However, we provide two examples of sequential decision-making mechanisms in order to illustrate the difference between success and satisfaction. In the context of the discussion of both notions we also address their relationship to different types of luck.
    Keywords: success; satisfaction; luck; power
    JEL: C79 D02 D71
    Date: 2012–03–27
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:dgr:uvatin:20120030&r=gth
  16. By: Changxia Ke; Kai A. Konrad; Florian Morath
    Abstract: Victorious alliances often fight about the spoils of war. We consider experimentally when members of victorious alliances accept a peaceful division of the spoils, and when they fight against each other, and how the inability to commit to a peaceful division affects their effort contributions in their fight against a common enemy. First, we find that an asymmetric split of the prize induces a higher likelihood of internal fight and, in turn, reduces the effort contributions in the fight against a joint enemy. Second, non-binding declarations on how to divide the spoils in case of victory do not help to mitigate the hold-up problem.
    Keywords: Conflict, contest, alliance, hold-up problem, experiment
    JEL: D72 D74
    Date: 2012–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:mpi:wpaper:alliances_in_the_shadow_of_conflict&r=gth
  17. By: Max Blouin
    Abstract: This paper presents a theoretical model of conflict between two players, with intervention by a peacekeeping force. Peacekeepers are treated as a military contingent, capable of taking sides, acting as a third (independent) side in the war, or remaining inactive, depending on circumstances. This departs from previous models, in which peacekeeping was no more than a parameter affecting players' fighting costs. The main result is an optimal deployment strategy by peacekeepers, detailing the nature and level of intervention required under different circumstances; a strategy which results in the lowest possible level of warfare between the two antagonists. The credible threat of force (rather than mere intervention) is the strategy's key component.
    Keywords: Peacekeeping, conflict, responsibility to protect (R2P)
    JEL: D74 F53 H56
    Date: 2012
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:lvl:lacicr:1235&r=gth

This nep-gth issue is ©2012 by Laszlo A. Koczy. It is provided as is without any express or implied warranty. It may be freely redistributed in whole or in part for any purpose. If distributed in part, please include this notice.
General information on the NEP project can be found at http://nep.repec.org. For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese at <director@nep.repec.org>. Put “NEP” in the subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.