nep-gth New Economics Papers
on Game Theory
Issue of 2011‒08‒09
fifteen papers chosen by
Laszlo A. Koczy
Hungarian Academy of Sciences and Obuda University

  1. The Strategic Use of Ambiguity By Frank Riedel; Linda Sass
  2. On the existence of Berge's strong equilibrium By Messaoud Deghdak; Monique Florenzano
  3. The Minority Game Unpacked: Coordination and Competition in a Team-based Experiment By Giovanna Devetag; Francesca Pancotto; Thomas Brenner
  4. What drives failure to maximize payoffs in the lab ? A test of the inequality aversion hypothesis By Nicolas Jacquemet; Adam Zylbersztejn
  5. Reciprocal Relationships and Mechanism Design By Celik, Gorkem; Peters, Michael
  6. On the equivalence of Bayesian and dominant strategy implementation in a general class of social choice problems By Jacob K. Goeree; Alexey Kushnir
  7. The probability of nontrivial common knowledge By Andrea Collevecchio; Marco LiCalzi
  8. Some conjectures on the two main power indices By Fabrice Barthelemy; Mathieu Martin; Bertrand Tchantcho
  9. Sticky wages in search and matching models in the short and long run By Christopher Reicher
  10. Intrafirm conflicts and interfirm competition By Güth, Werner; Pull, Kerstin; Stadler, Manfred
  11. Trade Policy Making in a Model of Legislative Bargaining By Levent Celik; Bilgehan Karabay; John McLaren
  12. A comparison between the methods of apportionment using power indices: the case of the U.S. presidential elections By Fabrice Barthelemy; Mathieu Martin
  13. The Present and Future of Game Theory By Martin Shubik
  14. Is population growth conducive to the sustainability of cooperation? By Stark, Oded; Jakubek, Marcin
  15. Exchange of private demand information by simultaneous signaling By Stadler, Manfred

  1. By: Frank Riedel (Institute of Mathematical Economics, Bielefeld University); Linda Sass (Institute of Mathematical Economics, Bielefeld University)
    Abstract: Ambiguity can be used as a strategic device in some situations. To demonstrate this, we propose and study a framework for normal form games where players can use Knightian uncertainty strategically. In such Ellsberg games, players may use Ellsberg urns in addition to the standard objective mixed strategies. We assume that players are ambiguity-averse in the sense of Gilboa and Schmeidler. While classical Nash equilibria remain equilibria in the new game, there arise new Ellsberg equilibria that can be quite different from Nash equilibria. A negotiation game with three players illustrates this finding. Another class of examples shows the use of ambiguity in mediation. We also highlight some conceptually interesting properties of Ellsberg equilibria in two person games with conflicting interests.
    Date: 2011–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:bie:wpaper:452&r=gth
  2. By: Messaoud Deghdak (Laboratoire de Mathématiques Appliquées et Modélisation - Département de Mathématiques); Monique Florenzano (CES - Centre d'économie de la Sorbonne - CNRS : UMR8174 - Université Panthéon-Sorbonne - Paris I)
    Abstract: In this paper, we establish the existence of Berge's strong equilibrium for games with n persons in infinite dimensional strategy spaces in the case where the payoff function of each player is quasi-concave. Moreover, we study the continuity of Berge's strong equilibrium correspondence and prove that most of Berge's strong games are essential.
    Keywords: Nash equilibrium, strong Berge equilibrium, fixed point, essential games.
    Date: 2011–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hal:cesptp:halshs-00611851&r=gth
  3. By: Giovanna Devetag; Francesca Pancotto; Thomas Brenner
    Abstract: In minority games, players in a group must decide at each round which of two available options to choose, knowing that only subjects who picked the minority option obtain a positive reward. Previous experiments on the minority and similar congestion games have shown that players interacting repeatedly are remarkably able to coordinate efficiently, despite not conforming to Nash equilibrium behavior. We conduct an experiment on a minority-of-three game in which each player is a team composed by three subjects. Each team can freely discuss its strategies in the game and decisions must be made via a majority rule. Team discussions are recorded and their content analyzed to detect evidence of strategy co-evolution among teams playing together. Our main results of team discussion analysis show no evidence supporting the mixed strategy Nash equilibrium solution, and support a low-rationality, backward-looking approach to model behavior in the game, more consistent with reinforcement learning models than with belief-based models. Showing level-2 rationality (i.e., reasoning about others' beliefs) is positively and significantly correlated with higher than average earnings in the game, showing that a mildly sophisticated approach pays off. In addition, teams that are more successful tend to become more egocentric over time, paying more attention to their own past successes than to the behavior of other teams. Finally, we find evidence of mutual adaptation over time, as teams that are more strategic (i.e., they pay more attention to other teams' moves) induce competing teams to be more egocentric instead. Our results contribute to the understanding of coordination dynamics resting on heterogeneity and co-evolution of decision rules rather than on conformity to equilibrium behavior. In addition, they provide support at the decision process level to the validity of modeling behavior using low-rationality reinforcement learning models.
    Keywords: coordination, minority game, market efficiency, information, self-organization, reinforcement learning
    JEL: C72 C91 C92
    Date: 2011
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:trn:utwpce:1102&r=gth
  4. By: Nicolas Jacquemet (CES - Centre d'économie de la Sorbonne - CNRS : UMR8174 - Université Panthéon-Sorbonne - Paris I, EEP-PSE - Ecole d'Économie de Paris - Paris School of Economics - Ecole d'Économie de Paris); Adam Zylbersztejn (CES - Centre d'économie de la Sorbonne - CNRS : UMR8174 - Université Panthéon-Sorbonne - Paris I)
    Abstract: In experiments based on the Beard and Beil (1994) game, second movers very often fail to select the decision that maximizes both players payoff. This note reports on a new experimental treatment, in which we neutralize the potential effect of inequality aversion on the likelihood of this behavior. We show this behavior is robust to this change, even after allowing for repetition-based learning.
    Keywords: Coordination failure, laboratory experiments, aversion to inequality.
    Date: 2011–06
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hal:cesptp:halshs-00611696&r=gth
  5. By: Celik, Gorkem; Peters, Michael
    Abstract: We study an incomplete information game in which players are involved in a reciprocal relationship that allows them to coordinate their actions by contracting among themselves. We model this as a competing mechanism game in which players have the ability to write contracts. We characterize the set of outcome functions that can be supported as equilibrium in this enhanced game. We use our characterization to show that the set of supportable outcomes is bigger than the set of outcomes supported by a centralized mechanism designer who can offer mechanisms in which all players participate. The difference is that the contracting game makes it possible for players to convey partial information about their type at the time they offer contracts.
    Date: 2011–08–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ubc:pmicro:gorkem_celik-2011-19&r=gth
  6. By: Jacob K. Goeree; Alexey Kushnir
    Abstract: We consider a standard social choice environment with linear utilities and independent, one-dimensional, private values. We provide a short and constructive proof that for any Bayesian incentive compatible mechanism there exists an equivalent dominant strategy incentive compatible mechanism that delivers the same interim expected utilities for all agents. We demonstrate the usefulness and applicability of our approach with several examples. Finally, we show that the equivalence between Bayesian and dominant strategy implementation breaks down when utilities are non-linear or when values are interdependent, multi-dimensional, or correlated.
    Date: 2011–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:zur:econwp:021&r=gth
  7. By: Andrea Collevecchio (Department of Management, Università Ca' Foscari Venezia); Marco LiCalzi (Department of Management, Università Ca' Foscari Venezia)
    Abstract: We study the probability that two or more agents can attain common knowledge of nontrivial events when the size of the state space grows large. We adopt the standard epistemic model where the knowledge of an agent is represented by a partition of the state space. Each agent is endowed with a partition generated by a random scheme. Assuming that agents' partitions are independently and identically distributed, we prove that the asymptotic probability of nontrivial common knowledge undergoes a phase transition. Regardless of the number of agents, when their cognitive capacity is suciently large, the probability goes to one; and when it is small, it goes to zero.
    Keywords: Common knowledge; Epistemic game theory; Random partitions
    JEL: C72 D83
    Date: 2011–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:vnm:wpdman:6&r=gth
  8. By: Fabrice Barthelemy; Mathieu Martin; Bertrand Tchantcho (THEMA, Universite de Cergy-Pontoise; THEMA, Universite de Cergy-Pontoise; University of Yaounde I, Ecole Normale Superieure, Cameroon, PO Box 47 Yaounde)
    Abstract: The purpose of this paper is to present a structural specification of the Shapley- Shubik and Banzhaf power indices in a weighted voting rule. We compare them in term of the cardinality of the sets of power vectors (PV). This is done in different situations where the quota or the number of seats are fixed or not.
    Keywords: Shapley-Shubik, Banzhaf, power index, power vectors.
    JEL: C7 D7
    Date: 2011
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ema:worpap:2011-14&r=gth
  9. By: Christopher Reicher
    Abstract: This paper documents the short run and long run behavior of the search and matching model with staggered Nash wage bargaining. It turns out that there is a strong tradeoff inherent in assuming that previously bargained sticky wages apply to new hires. If sticky wages apply to new hires, then the staggered Nash bargaining model can generate realistic volatility in labor input, but it predicts a strong counterfactually negative long run relationship between inflation and unemployment. This finding is robust to including a microeconomically realistic degree of indexation of wages to inflation. The lack of a negative long run relationship between trend inflation and unemployment provides indirect evidence against the proposed mechanism that high inflation systematically makes new hiring more profitable by depressing the real wages of new hires
    Keywords: Sticky wages, staggered Nash bargaining, trend inflation, unemployment, search and matching
    JEL: E24 E25 J23 J31
    Date: 2011–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:kie:kieliw:1722&r=gth
  10. By: Güth, Werner; Pull, Kerstin; Stadler, Manfred
    Abstract: We study strategic interfirm competition allowing for internal conflicts in each seller firm. Intrafirm conflicts are captured by a multi-agent framework with principals implementing a revenue sharing scheme. For a given number of agents, interfirm competition leads to a higher revenue share for the agents, higher equilibrium effort levels and higher agent utility, but lower profits for the firms. The winners from antitrust policy are thus not only the consumers but also the agents employed by the competing firms. --
    Keywords: agency theory,strategic interfirm competition,revenue sharing
    JEL: C72 L22 M52
    Date: 2011
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:zbw:tuewef:14&r=gth
  11. By: Levent Celik; Bilgehan Karabay; John McLaren
    Abstract: In democracies, trade policy is the result of interactions among many agents with different agendas. In accordance with this observation, we construct a dynamic model of legislative trade policy-making in the realm of distributive politics. An economy consists of different sectors, each of which is concentrated in one or more electoral districts. Each district is represented by a legislator in the Congress. Legislative process is modeled as a multilateral sequential bargaining game a la Baron and Ferejohn (1989). Some surprising results emerge: bargaining can be welfare-worsening for all participants; legislators may vote for bills that make their constituents worse off; identical industries will receive very different levels of tariff. The results pose a challenge to empirical work, since equilibrium trade policy is a function not only of economic fundamentals but also of political variables at the time of congressional negotiations – some of them random realizations of mixed bargaining strategies.
    JEL: C72 C78 D72 F13
    Date: 2011–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:17262&r=gth
  12. By: Fabrice Barthelemy; Mathieu Martin (THEMA, Universite de Cergy-Pontoise; THEMA, Universite de Cergy-Pontoise)
    Abstract: In this paper, we compare five well-known methods of apportionment, the ones by Adams, Dean, Hill, Webster and Jefferson. The criteria used for this comparison is the minimization of a distance between a power vector and a population vector. The power is measured with the well-known Banzhaf power index and the populations are the ones of the different States of the U.S. We first explain under which conditions this comparison makes sense. We then compare the apportionment methods in terms of their ability to bring closer the power of the States to their relative population. The U.S. presidential election by Electors is studied through 22 censuses since 1790. Our analysis is largely based on the book written by Balinski and Young (2001). The empirical findings are linked with theoretical results.
    Keywords: Banzhaf index, methods of apportionment, distances, balance population-power.
    JEL: C7 D7
    Date: 2011
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ema:worpap:2011-13&r=gth
  13. By: Martin Shubik
    Date: 2011–07–31
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cla:levarc:786969000000000173&r=gth
  14. By: Stark, Oded; Jakubek, Marcin
    Abstract: This paper asks whether population growth is conducive to the sustainability of cooperation. A simple model is developed in which farmers who live around a circular lake engage in trade with their adjacent neighbors. The payoffs from this activity are governed by a prisoner's dilemma rule of engagement. Every farmer has one son when the population is not growing, or two sons when it is growing. In the former case, the son takes over the farm when his father dies. In the latter case, one son stays on his father's farm, whereas the other son settles around another lake, along with the other sons of the other farmers. During his childhood, each son observes the strategies and the payoffs of his father and of the trading partners of his father, and imitates the most successful strategy when starting farming on his own. Then mutant defectors are introduced into an all-cooperator community. The defector strategy may spread. A comparison is drawn between the impact in terms of the sustainability of cooperation of the appearance of the mutants in a population that is not growing, and in one that is growing. It is shown that the ex-ante probability of sustaining the cooperation strategy is higher for a community that is growing than for a stagnant community. --
    Keywords: Population growth,Imitation,Sustainability of cooperation
    JEL: C72 D01 D83 J19 J62 R12 R23
    Date: 2011
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:zbw:tuewef:15&r=gth
  15. By: Stadler, Manfred
    Abstract: As is well-known from the literature on oligopolistic competition with incomplete information, firms have an incentive to share private demand information. However, by assuming verifiability of demand data, these models ignore the possibility of strategic misinformation. We show that if firms can send misleading demand information, they will do so. Furthermore, we derive a costly signaling mechanism implementing demand revelation, even without verifiability. For the case of a gamma distribution of the firms' demand variables, we prove that the expected gross gains from information revelation exceed the expected cost of signaling if the skewness of the distribution is sufficiently large and the products are sufficiently differentiated. --
    Keywords: Information sharing,simultaneous signaling,demand uncertainty
    JEL: C73 D82 L13
    Date: 2011
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:zbw:tuewef:17&r=gth

This nep-gth issue is ©2011 by Laszlo A. Koczy. It is provided as is without any express or implied warranty. It may be freely redistributed in whole or in part for any purpose. If distributed in part, please include this notice.
General information on the NEP project can be found at http://nep.repec.org. For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese at <director@nep.repec.org>. Put “NEP” in the subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.