nep-gth New Economics Papers
on Game Theory
Issue of 2008‒11‒04
seventeen papers chosen by
Laszlo A. Koczy
Budapest Tech and Maastricht University

  1. Measuring influence in command games By Michel Grabisch; Agnieszka Rusinowska
  2. "Need to Know" Versus "Spread the Word": Collective Action in the Multi-Player Electronic Mail Game By Kris De Jaegher
  3. Generalized projection dynamics in evolutionary game theory By Reinoud Joosten; Berend Roorda
  4. On the vertices of the k-addiive core By Michel Grabisch; Pedro Miranda
  5. Measuring influence among players with an ordered set of possible actions By Michel Grabisch; Agnieszka Rusinowska
  6. Interaction sheaves on continuous domains By Joseph Abdou; Hans Keiding
  7. An extension of Reny's theorem without quasiconcavity By Philippe Bich
  8. Coalition Formation and the Ancillary Benefits of Climate Policy By Rübbelke, Dirk T.G.; Finus, Michael
  9. Indirect Reciprocity and Strategic Reputation Building in an Experimental Helping Game By Dirk Engelmann; Urs Fischbacher
  10. "Voluntarily Separable Repeated Prisoner's Dilemma" By Takako Fujiwara-Greve; Masahiro Okuno-Fujiwara
  11. Power distribution and endogenous segregation By Catherine Bros
  12. Coral Games and the Core of Cores By James Bono
  13. An answer to a question of herings et al By Philippe Bich
  14. A Stability Index for Local Effectivity Functions By Joseph Abdou
  15. Sequential Pre-Marital Investment Games: Implications for Unemployment By James W. Boudreau
  16. Bargaining over public goods By Julio Davila; Jan Eeckhout; César Martinelli
  17. Attitude toward imprecise information By Thibault Gajdos; Takashi Hayashi; Jean-Marc Tallon; Jean-Christophe Vergnaud

  1. By: Michel Grabisch (CES - Centre d'économie de la Sorbonne - CNRS : UMR8174 - Université Panthéon-Sorbonne - Paris I); Agnieszka Rusinowska (GATE - Groupe d'analyse et de théorie économique - CNRS : UMR5824 - Université Lumière - Lyon II - Ecole Normale Supérieure Lettres et Sciences Humaines)
    Abstract: In the paper, we study a relation between command games proposed by Hu and Shapley and an influence model. We show that our framework of influence is more general than the framework of the command games. We define several influence functions which capture the command structure. These functions are compatible with the command games, in the sense that each commandable player for a coalition in the command game is a follower of the coalition under the command influence function. For some influence functions we define the command games such that the influence functions are compatible with these games. We show that not for all influence functions such command games exist. Moreover, we propose a more general definition of the influence index and show that some power indices, which can be used in the command games, coincide with some expressions of the weighted influence indices. We show exact relations between an influence function and a follower function, between a command game and commandable players, and between influence functions and command games. An example of the Confucian model of society is broadly examined.
    Keywords: Banzhaf index ; Coleman indices ; command game ; follower of a coalition ; influence function ; influence indices ; Shapley-Shubik index
    Date: 2008
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hal:paris1:halshs-00269084_v1&r=gth
  2. By: Kris De Jaegher
    Abstract: As shown by Rubinstein (1989, AER), in the two-player electronic mail game, players are better off if the extent to which they can check each other’s information, check each other’s information about each other’s information, etc., is limited. This paper investigates to what extent this result extends to the multi-player electronic mail game. It is shown that, contrary to the two-player game, the multi-player game has a plethora of equilibria. If players play inefficient equilibria where they require a specific communication network to be established in order to achieve collective action, then Rubinstein’s results extend. However, contrary to the two-player game, the multi-player game also has equilibria where players find many alternative communication networks sufficient to undertake collective action. If players play such equilibria, then contrary to what is the case in the two-player electronic mail game they can become better off with more information.
    Keywords: Multi-Player Electronic Mail Game, Collective Action, Communication Networks.
    JEL: D82 D85 D71
    Date: 2008–10
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:use:tkiwps:0831&r=gth
  3. By: Reinoud Joosten; Berend Roorda
    Abstract: We introduce a new kind of projection dynamics by employing a ray-projection both locally and globally. By global (local) we mean a projection of a vector (close to the unit simplex) unto the unit simplex along a ray through the origin. Using a correspondence between local and global ray-projection dynamics we prove that every interior evolutionarily stable strategy is an asymptotically stable fixed point. We also show that every strict equilibrium is an evolutionarily stable state and an evolutionarily stable equilibrium. Then, we employ several projections on a wider set of functions derived from the payoff structure. This yields an interesting class of so-called generalized projection dynamics which contains best-response, logit, replicator, and Brown-Von-Neumann dynamics among others.
    Keywords: evolutionary game theory, projection dynamics, orthogonal projection, ray projection, asymptotical and evolutionary stability Length 27 pages
    JEL: A12 C62 C72 C73 D83
    Date: 2008–10
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:esi:evopap:2008-11&r=gth
  4. By: Michel Grabisch (CES - Centre d'économie de la Sorbonne - CNRS : UMR8174 - Université Panthéon-Sorbonne - Paris I); Pedro Miranda (Universidad Complutense de Madrid - Universidad Complutense de Madrid)
    Abstract: The core of a game $v$ on $N$, which is the set of additive games $\phi$ dominating $v$ such that $\phi(N)=v(N)$, is a central notion in cooperative game theory, decision making and in combinatorics, where it is related to submodular functions, matroids and the greedy algorithm. In many cases however, the core is empty, and alternative solutions have to be found. We define the $k$-additive core by replacing additive games by $k$-additive games in the definition of the core, where $k$-additive games are those games whose M\"obius transform vanishes for subsets of more than $k$ elements. For a sufficiently high value of $k$, the $k$-additive core is nonempty, and is a convex closed polyhedron. Our aim is to establish results similar to the classical results of Shapley and Ichiishi on the core of convex games (corresponds to Edmonds' theorem for the greedy algorithm), which characterize the vertices of the core.
    Date: 2008
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hal:paris1:hal-00321625_v1&r=gth
  5. By: Michel Grabisch (CES - Centre d'économie de la Sorbonne - CNRS : UMR8174 - Université Panthéon-Sorbonne - Paris I); Agnieszka Rusinowska (GATE - Groupe d'analyse et de théorie économique - CNRS : UMR5824 - Université Lumière - Lyon II - Ecole Normale Supérieure Lettres et Sciences Humaines)
    Abstract: In the paper, we introduce and study generalized weighted influence indices of a coalition on a player, where players have an ordered set of possible actions. Each player has an inclination to choose one of the actions. Due to influence of a coalition of other players, a final decision of the player may be different from his original inclination. An influence in such situations is measured by the general weighted influence index. In a particular case, the decision of the player may be closer to the inclination of the influencing coalition than his inclination was. The weighted influence index which captures such a case is called the positive weighted influence index. We also consider the negative weighted influence index, where a final decision of the player goes farther away from the inclination of the influencing coalition. Some special cases of the weighted influence indices, called a possibility influence index and an equidistributed influence index, are also defined. We consider different influence functions and study their properties. A set of followers and a set of a conditional followers of a given coalition are defined, and their properties are analyzed. We define the concepts of success, decisiveness, luck, and failure for the multi-choice model of influence.
    Keywords: decisiveness ; follower of a coalition ; influence function ; influence indices ; success
    Date: 2008
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hal:paris1:halshs-00260863_v1&r=gth
  6. By: Joseph Abdou (CES - Centre d'économie de la Sorbonne - CNRS : UMR8174 - Université Panthéon-Sorbonne - Paris I, EEP-PSE - Ecole d'Économie de Paris - Paris School of Economics - Ecole d'Économie de Paris); Hans Keiding (University of Copenhagen - Institute of Economics)
    Abstract: We introduce a description of the power structure which is inherent in a strategic game form using the concept of an interaction sheaf. The latter assigns to each open set of outcomes a set of interaction arrays, specifying the changes that coalitions can make if outcome belongs to this open set. The interaction sheaf generalizes the notion of effectivity functions which has been widely used in implementation theory, taking into consideration that changes in outcome may be sustained not only by single coalitions but possibly by several coalitions, depending on the underlying strategy choices. Also, it allows us to consider game forms with not necessarily finite sets of outcomes, generalizing the results on solvability of game forms obtained in the finite case in Abdou and Keiding (2003).
    Keywords: Nash equilibrium, strong equilibrium, solvability, effectivity, acyclicity.
    Date: 2008–04
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hal:paris1:halshs-00289299_v1&r=gth
  7. By: Philippe Bich (CES - Centre d'économie de la Sorbonne - CNRS : UMR8174 - Université Panthéon-Sorbonne - Paris I)
    Abstract: In a recent but well known paper, Reny has proved the existence of Nash equilibria for compact and quasiconcave games, with possibly discontinuous payoff functions. In this paper, we prove that the quasiconcavity assumption in Reny's theorem can be weakened: roughly, we introduce a measure allowing to localize the lack of quasiconcavity; this allows to refine the analysis of equilibrium existence
    Keywords: Nash equilibrium, existence, discontinuous games, non quasiconcave
    Date: 2008–09–20
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hal:paris1:halshs-00323348_v1&r=gth
  8. By: Rübbelke, Dirk T.G.; Finus, Michael
    Abstract: Several studies found ancillary benefits of environmental policy to be of considerable size. These additional private benefits imply not only higher cooperative but also noncooperative abatement targets. However, beyond these largely undisputed important quantitative effects, there are qualitative and strategic implications associated with ancillary benefits: climate policy is no longer a pure but an impure public good. In this paper, we investigate these implications in a setting of non-cooperative coalition formation. In particular, we address the following questions. 1) Do ancillary benefits increase participation in international environmental agreements? 2) Do ancillary benefits raise the success of these treaties in welfare terms?
    Keywords: impure public goods; game theory; coalition formation; climate policy; ancillary benefits
    Date: 2008–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:stl:stledp:2008-13&r=gth
  9. By: Dirk Engelmann; Urs Fischbacher
    Abstract: We study indirect reciprocity and strategic reputation building in an experimental helping game. At any time only half of the subjects can build a reputation. This allows us to study both pure indirect reciprocity that is not contaminated by strategic reputation building and the impact of incentives for strategic reputation building on the helping rate. We find that pure indirect reciprocity exists, but also that the helping decisions are substantially a!ected by strategic considerations. We find that the behavioral pattern can best be captured by non-selfish preferences as assumed by reciprocity models. Finally, we find that strategic do better than non-strategic players and non-reciprocal do better than reciprocal players, casting doubt on previously proposed evolutionary explanations for indirect reciprocity.
    Keywords: indirect reciprocity, reputation, experimental economics
    Date: 2008
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:twi:respas:0034&r=gth
  10. By: Takako Fujiwara-Greve (Faculty of Economics, Keio University); Masahiro Okuno-Fujiwara (Faculty of Economics, University of Tokyo)
    Abstract: Ordinary repeated games do not apply to real societies where one can cheat and escape from partners. We formulate a model of endogenous relationships that a player can unilaterally end and start with a randomly-assigned new partner with no information flow. Focusing on two-person, two-action Prisoner's Dilemma, we show that the endogenous duration of partnerships generates a significantly different evolutionary stability structure from ordinary random matching games. Monomorphic equilibria require initial trust-building, while a polymorphic equilibrium includes earlier cooperators than any strategy in monomorphic equilibria and is thus more efficient. This is due to the nonlinearity of average payoffs.Length: 37pages
    Date: 2008–10
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:tky:fseres:2008cf599&r=gth
  11. By: Catherine Bros (CES - Centre d'économie de la Sorbonne - CNRS : UMR8174 - Université Panthéon-Sorbonne - Paris I)
    Abstract: The aim of this paper is to provide a detailed analysis of the process of segregation formation. The claim is that segregation does not originate from prejudice or exogenous psychological factors. Rather it is the product of strategic interactions among social groups in a setting where one group has captured power. While using a model featuring random matching and repeated games, it is shown that whenever one group seizes power, members of other groups will perceive additional value in forging long term relationships with the mighty. They will systematically cooperate with the latter either because it is in their interest to do so or because they do not have other choice. The mighty natural response to this yearning to cooperate is to refuse intergroup relationships. The dominated group will best reply to this new situation by in turn rejecting the relationships and a segregation equilibrium emerges. Segregation stems from the systematic cooperation by one group with another. However, not all societies that have experienced power captures converge towards segregation. It is shown that the proportion of individuals that are actually powerful within the mighty group determines convergence towards segregation.
    Keywords: Segration, discrimination, power, caste, repeated games, prisoner's dilemma, clubs, status, social organizations.
    Date: 2008–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hal:paris1:halshs-00204974_v1&r=gth
  12. By: James Bono
    Abstract: Casual observation reveals that groups of people interact on many levels simultane- ously. Examples include political party formation and interaction; the interaction of ¯rms in research consortia; and labor union and confederation formation. In this paper, a model of hierarchical group structures is developed. The model generalizes the existing coalitional theory in several ways and reveals a new connection between characteristic and partition function theories; that they are both valuable components of an overall theory. The stability concept that emerges is called the core of cores. Several results are presented, including necessary and su±cient conditions for the existence of the core of cores and a theorem that demonstrates the relationship between the cores of each level of the organizational structure and the core of cores. The results establish that stability can arise from any combination of stable and unstable components, and suggest a re-thinking of existing coalitional models, taking into account the e®ect of \nearby" games. The framework developed here has immediate applications to various topics in political econ- omy and industrial organization, such as representative voting and corporate mergers.
    Keywords: The Core, Complexity in Game Theory, Hierarchies of Groups
    JEL: C62 C71 C79 D72
    Date: 2008–09
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:amu:wpaper:1808&r=gth
  13. By: Philippe Bich (CES - Centre d'économie de la Sorbonne - CNRS : UMR8174 - Université Panthéon-Sorbonne - Paris I)
    Abstract: One answers to an open question of Herings et al. (2008), by proving that their fixed point theorem for discontinuous functions works for mappings defined on convex compact subset of $\R^n$, and not only polytopes. This fixed point theorem can be applied to the problem of Nash equilibrium existence in discontinuous games.
    Keywords: fixed point theorem; discontinuity; nash equilibrium
    Date: 2008–02
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hal:paris1:halshs-00265464_v1&r=gth
  14. By: Joseph Abdou (CES - Centre d'économie de la Sorbonne - CNRS : UMR8174 - Université Panthéon-Sorbonne - Paris I, EEP-PSE - Ecole d'Économie de Paris - Paris School of Economics - Ecole d'Économie de Paris)
    Abstract: We study the structure of unstable local effectivity functions defined for n players and p alternatives. A stability index based on the notion of cycle is introduced. In the particular case of simple games, the stability index is closely related to the Nakamura Number. In general it may be any integer between 2 and p. We prove that the stability index for maximal effectivity functions and for maximal local effectivity functions is either 2 or 3.
    Keywords: Effectivity function, local effectivity function, acyclicity, stability index, Nakamura Number, acyclicity.
    Date: 2008–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hal:paris1:halshs-00331223_v1&r=gth
  15. By: James W. Boudreau (University of Connecticut)
    Abstract: Agents on the same side of a two-sided matching market (such as the marriage or labor market) compete with each other by making self-enhancing investments to improve their worth in the eyes of potential partners. Because these expenditures generally occur prior to matching, this activity has come to be known in recent literature (Peters, 2007) as pre-marital investment. This paper builds on that literature by considering the case of sequential pre-marital investment, analyzing a matching game in which one side of the market invests first, followed by the other. Interpreting the first group of agents as workers and the other group as firms, the paper provides a new perspective on the incentive structure that is inherent in labor markets. It also demonstrates that a positive rate of unemployment can exist even in the absence of matching frictions. Policy implications follow, as the prevailing set of equilibria can be altered by restricting entry into the workforce, providing unemployment insurance, or subsidizing pre-marital investment.
    Keywords: Matching, pre-marital investment, unemployment.
    JEL: C78 H30 E24
    Date: 2008–10
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:uct:uconnp:2008-45&r=gth
  16. By: Julio Davila (CES - Centre d'économie de la Sorbonne - CNRS : UMR8174 - Université Panthéon-Sorbonne - Paris I, EEP-PSE - Ecole d'Économie de Paris - Paris School of Economics - Ecole d'Économie de Paris); Jan Eeckhout (University of Pennsylvania - Department of Economics); César Martinelli (Centro de Investigacion Economica - Instituto Tecnologico Autonomo)
    Abstract: In a simple public good economy, we propose a natural bargaining procedure whose equilibria converge to Lindahl allocations as the cost of bargaining vanishes. The procedure splits the decision over the allocation in a decision about personalized prices and a decision about output levels for the public good. Since this procedure does not assume price-taking behavior, it provides a strategic foundation for the personalized taxes inherent to the Lindahl solution to the public goods problem.
    Keywords: Public goods, bargaining, alternating offers.
    Date: 2008–06
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hal:paris1:halshs-00289435_v1&r=gth
  17. By: Thibault Gajdos (CES - Centre d'économie de la Sorbonne - CNRS : UMR8174 - Université Panthéon-Sorbonne - Paris I, EEP-PSE - Ecole d'Économie de Paris - Paris School of Economics - Ecole d'Économie de Paris); Takashi Hayashi (Department of Economics, University of Texas at Austin - University of Texas at Austin); Jean-Marc Tallon (CES - Centre d'économie de la Sorbonne - CNRS : UMR8174 - Université Panthéon-Sorbonne - Paris I, EEP-PSE - Ecole d'Économie de Paris - Paris School of Economics - Ecole d'Économie de Paris); Jean-Christophe Vergnaud (CES - Centre d'économie de la Sorbonne - CNRS : UMR8174 - Université Panthéon-Sorbonne - Paris I, EEP-PSE - Ecole d'Économie de Paris - Paris School of Economics - Ecole d'Économie de Paris)
    Abstract: This paper presents an axiomatic model of decision making under uncertainty which incorporates objective but imprecise information. Information is assumed to take the form of a probability-possibility set, that is, a set $P$ of probability measures on the state space. The decision maker is told that the true probability law lies in $P$ and is assumed to rank pairs of the form $(P,f) $ where $f$ is an act mapping states into outcomes. Thekey representation result delivers maxmin expected utility where the min operator ranges over a set of probability priors --just as in the maxmin expected utility (MEU) representation result of \cite{GILB/SCHM/89}. However, unlike the MEU representation, the representation here also delivers a mapping, $\varphi$, which links the probability-possibility set, describing the availableinformation, to the set of revealed priors. The mapping $\varphi$ is shown to represent the decision maker's attitude to imprecise information: under our axioms, the set of representation priors is constituted as a selection from the probability-possibility set.This allows both expected utility when the selected set is a singleton and extreme pessimism when the selected set is the same as the probability-possibility set, i.e. , $\varphi$ is the identity mapping. We define a notion of comparative imprecision aversion and show it is characterized by inclusion of the sets of revealedprobability distributions, irrespective of the utility functions that capture risk attitude. We also identify an explicit attitude toward imprecision that underlies usual hedging axioms. Finally, we characterize, under extra axioms, a more specific functional form, in which the set of selected probability distributions is obtained by (i) solving for the ``mean value'' of the probability-possibility set, and (ii) shrinking the probability-possibility set toward the mean value to a degree determined by preferences.
    Keywords: precise information, imprecision aversion, multiple priors, Steiner point.
    Date: 2008–05
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hal:paris1:halshs-00177378_v1&r=gth

This nep-gth issue is ©2008 by Laszlo A. Koczy. It is provided as is without any express or implied warranty. It may be freely redistributed in whole or in part for any purpose. If distributed in part, please include this notice.
General information on the NEP project can be found at http://nep.repec.org. For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese at <director@nep.repec.org>. Put “NEP” in the subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.