nep-exp New Economics Papers
on Experimental Economics
Issue of 2013‒08‒23
fourteen papers chosen by
Daniel Houser
George Mason University

  1. Investment Behavior of Ugandan Smallholder Farmers: An Experimental Analysis By Ihli, Hanna Julia; Mußhoff, Oliver
  2. (Public) Good Examples - On the Role of Limited Feedback in Voluntary Contribution Games By Bernd Irlenbusch; Rainer Michael Rilke
  3. Anchoring: A valid explanation for biased forecasts when rational predictions are easily accessible and well incentivized? By Meub, Lukas; Proeger, Till; Bizer, Kilian
  4. First- and Second-order Subjective Expectations in Strategic Decision-Making: Experimental Evidence By Charles Manski; Claudia Neri
  5. A comparison of endogenous and exogenous timing in a social learning experiment By Meub, Lukas; Proeger, Till; Hüning, Hendrik
  6. Preferences for Redistribution and Perception of Fairness: An Experimental Study By Ruben Durante; Louis Putterman; Joël van der Weele
  7. The role of emotions on risk aversion: a prospect theory experiment By Raymundo M. Campos-Vazquez; Emilio Cuilty
  8. Intertemporal stability of ambiguity preferences By Duersch, Peter; Römer, Daniel; Roth, Benjamin
  9. Price Competition in an Inflationary Environment By Duersch, Peter; Eife, Thomas
  10. Social Centipedes: the Role of Group Identity on Preferences and Reasoning By James Tremewan; Chloé Le Coq; Alexander D. Wagner
  11. Awards Unbundled: Evidence from a Natural Field Experiment By Nava Ashraf; Oriana Bandiera; Scott Lee
  12. Lying through Their Teeth: Third Party Advice and Truth Telling in a Strategy Proof Mechanism By Guillén, Pablo; Hing, Alexander
  13. Savings and Prize-Linked Savings Accounts By Atalay, Kadir; Bakhtiar, Fayzan; Cheung, Stephen L.; Slonim, Robert
  14. One Swallow Doesn't Make a Summer - A Note By Mitesh Kataria

  1. By: Ihli, Hanna Julia; Mußhoff, Oliver
    Abstract: In this study, we experimentally analyze the investment behavior of smallholder farmers in Uganda. We consider a problem of optimal stopping, stylizing an option to invest in a project. We ascertain whether, and to what extent, the real options approach and the classical investment theory can predict farmers’ investment behaviors. We also examine differences in the investment behavior with respect to the presence of a price floor, which is often used to stimulate investments. Furthermore, we look at learning effects. Our results show that both theories do not exactly explain the observed investment behavior. However, our results suggest that real options models better predict the decision behavior of farmers than the classical investment theory. The presence of a price floor and learning from personal experience during the experiment do not significantly affect the investment behavior. However, we find that specific socio-demographic and socio-economic characteristics affect the investment behavior of farmers.
    Keywords: experimental economics, investment, price floors, real options, Uganda, Farm Management, Institutional and Behavioral Economics, Political Economy, Risk and Uncertainty, C91, D03, D81, D92,
    Date: 2013–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ags:gagfdp:154775&r=exp
  2. By: Bernd Irlenbusch (University of Cologne); Rainer Michael Rilke (University of Cologne)
    Abstract: This paper experimentally investigates into the effects of limited feedback on contributions in a repeated public goods game. We test whether feedback about good examples (i.e., the respective maximum contribution in a period) in contrast to bad examples (i.e., the minimum contributions) induces higher contributions. When the selection of feedback is non-transparent to the subjects, good examples boost cooperation while bad examples hamper them. No significant differences are observed between providing good or bad examples, when the feedback selection rule is transparent. Our results shed new light on how to design feedback provision in public goods settings.
    Keywords: Public Goods, Feedback, Imperfect Conditional Cooperation, Experiment
    JEL: H41 C92 D82
    Date: 2013–08–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cgr:cgsser:04-04&r=exp
  3. By: Meub, Lukas; Proeger, Till; Bizer, Kilian
    Abstract: Behavioral biases in forecasting, particularly the lack of adjustment from current values and the overall clustering of forecasts, are increasingly explained as resulting from the anchoring heuristic. Nonetheless, the classical anchoring experiments presented in support of this interpretation lack external validity for economic domains, particularly monetary incentives, feedback for learning effects and a rational strategy of unbiased predictions. We introduce an experimental design that implements central aspects of forecasting to close the gap between empirical studies on forecasting quality and the laboratory evidence for anchoring effects. Comprising more than 5,000 individual forecasts by 455 participants, our study shows significant anchoring effects. Without monetary incentives, the share of rational predictions drops from 42% to 15% in the anchor's presence. Monetary incentives reduce the average bias to one-third of its original value. Additionally, the average anchor bias is doubled when task complexity is increased, and is quadrupled when the underlying risk is increased. The variance of forecasts is significantly reduced by the anchor once risk or cognitive load is increased. Subjects with higher cognitive abilities are on average less biased toward the anchor when task complexity is high. The anchoring bias in our repeated game is not influenced by learning effects, although feedback is provided. Our results support the assumption that biased forecasts and their specific variance can be ascribed to anchoring effects. --
    Keywords: anchoring,cognitive ability,forecasting,heuristics and biases,incentives,laboratory experiment
    JEL: C90 D03 D80 G17
    Date: 2013
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:zbw:cegedp:166&r=exp
  4. By: Charles Manski (Northwestern University); Claudia Neri (University of St.Gallen)
    Abstract: We study first- and second-order subjective expectations (beliefs) in strategic decision-making. We propose a method to elicit probabilistically both first- and second-order beliefs and apply the method to a Hide-and-Seek experiment. We study the relationship between choice and beliefs in terms of whether observed choice coincides with the optimal action given elicited beliefs. We study the relationship between first- and second-order beliefs under a coherence criterion. Weak coherence requires that if an event is assigned, according to first-order beliefs, a probability higher/lower/equal to the one assigned to another event, then the same holds according to second-order beliefs. Strong coherence requires the probability assigned according to first- and second-order beliefs to coincide. Evidence of heterogeneity across participants is reported. Verbal comments collected at the end of the experiment shed light on how subjects think and decide in a complex environment that is strategic, dynamic and populated by potentially heterogeneous individuals.
    Date: 2013
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:red:sed013:73&r=exp
  5. By: Meub, Lukas; Proeger, Till; Hüning, Hendrik
    Abstract: This paper experimentally investigates social learning in a two-agent prediction game with both exogenous and endogenous ordering of decisions and a continuous action space. Given that individuals regularly fail to apply rational timing, we refrain from implementing optimal timing of decisions conditional on signal strength. This always renders it optimal to outwait the other player regardless of private signals and induces a gamble on the optimal timing and action. In this setting, we compare exogenous and endogenous ordering in terms of informational efficiency, strategic delay and social welfare. We find that more efficient observational learning leads to more accurate predictions in the endogenous treatments and increases informational efficiency compared to the benchmark exogenous treatment. Overall, subjects act sensitively to waiting costs, with higher costs fostering earlier decisions that reduce informational efficiency. For a simple implementation of waiting costs, subjects more successfully internalize information externalities by adjusting their timing according to signal strength. Simultaneous decisions in endogenous ordering avoid observational learning and compensate the higher degree of rational decisions. Overall, endogenous timing has no net effect on social welfare, as gains in accuracy are fully compensated by waiting costs. Our results hold relevance for social learning environments characterized by a continuous action space and the endogenous timing of decisions. --
    Keywords: Endogenous Timing,Information Externalities,Laboratory Experiment,Social Learning,Strategic Delay
    JEL: C91 D82 D83
    Date: 2013
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:zbw:cegedp:167&r=exp
  6. By: Ruben Durante; Louis Putterman; Joël van der Weele
    Abstract: We conduct a laboratory experiment to study how demand for redistribution of income depends on self-interest, insurance motives, and social concerns relating to inequality and efficiency. Our choice environments feature large groups of subjects and real world framing, and differ with respect to the source of inequality (earned or arbitrary), the cost of taxation to the decision maker, the dead-weight loss of taxation, uncertainty about own pre-tax income, and whether the decisionmaker is affected by redistribution. We estimate utility weights for the different sources of demand for redistribution, with the potential to inform modeling in macroeconomics and political economy.
    Keywords: income distribution, political economy, redistribution, social preferences.
    Date: 2013
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:bro:econwp:2013-7&r=exp
  7. By: Raymundo M. Campos-Vazquez (El Colegio de Mexico); Emilio Cuilty (El Colegio de Mexico)
    Abstract: This study measures risk and loss aversion using Prospect Theory and the impact of emotions on those parameters. Our controlled experiment at two universities in Mexico City, using uncompensated students as research subjects, found results similar to those obtained by Tanaka et al. (2010). In order to study the role of emotions, we provided subjects with randomly varied information on rising deaths due to drug violence in Mexico and also on youth unemployment. In agreement with previous studies, we find that risk aversion on the gains domain decreases with age and income. We also find that loss aversion decreases with income and is less for students in public universities. With regard to emotions, risk aversion increases with sadness and loss aversion is negatively influenced by anger. On the loss domain, anger dominates sadness. On average, anger reduces loss aversion by half.
    Keywords: risk aversion; emotions; prospect theory; experiment; Mexico
    JEL: C93 D03 D12 O12 O54
    Date: 2013–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:emx:ceedoc:2013-05&r=exp
  8. By: Duersch, Peter; Römer, Daniel; Roth, Benjamin
    Abstract: To make predictions with theories, usually we assume an individual's characteristics such as uncertainty preferences to be stable over time. In this paper, we analyze the stability of ambiguity preferences experimentally. We repeatedly elicit ambiguity attitudes towards multiple 3-color Ellsberg urns over a period of two months. In our data, 57% of the choices are consistent with stable preferences over the time of observation. This share is significantly higher than random choices would suggest, but significantly lower than the level of consistency in a control treatment without a time lag (71%). Interestingly, for subjects who are able to recall their decision after two months correctly, the share of consistent choices does not drop significantly over time.
    Keywords: ambiguity; stability of preferences; experiment
    Date: 2013–08–13
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:awi:wpaper:0548&r=exp
  9. By: Duersch, Peter; Eife, Thomas
    Abstract: We study how inflation and deflation affect firms' ability to cooperate in an experimental Bertrand duopoly with differentiated products. We find that there is significantly less cooperation in the treatments with inflation and deflation compared to the no-inflation treatments. The difficulties to cooperate affect prices and welfare: Depending on the market structure, inflation and deflation lead to significantly lower (real) prices and higher welfare.
    Keywords: Bertrand Duopoly; Inflation; Experiment; Money Illusion
    Date: 2013–08–13
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:awi:wpaper:0547&r=exp
  10. By: James Tremewan; Chloé Le Coq; Alexander D. Wagner
    Abstract: Using a group identity manipulation we examine the role of social preferences in an experimental one-shot centipede game. Contrary to what social preference theory would predict, we fnd that players continue longer when playing with outgroup members. The explanation we provide for this result rests on two observations: (i) players should only stop if they are suffciently conident that their partner will stop at the next node, given the exponentially-increasing payoffs in the game, and (ii) players are more likely to have this degree of certainty if they are matched with someone from the same group, whom they view as similar to themselves and thus predictable. We find strong statistical support for this argument. We conclude that group identity not only impacts a player's utility function, as identifed in earlier research, but also affects her reasoning about her partner's behavior.
    JEL: C72 C91 C92 D83
    Date: 2013–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:vie:viennp:1305&r=exp
  11. By: Nava Ashraf; Oriana Bandiera; Scott Lee
    Abstract: Organizations often use awards to incentivize performance. We design a field experiment to unbundle the mechanisms through which awards may affect behavior: by facilitating social comparison and by conferring recognition and visibility. In a nationwide health worker training program in Zambia, employer recognition and social visibility increase performance while social comparison reduces it, especially for low-ability trainees. These effects appear when treatments are announced and persist through training. The findings are consistent with a model of optimal expectations in which low-ability individuals exert low effort in order to avoid information about their relative ability.
    Keywords: awards, social comparison, optimal expectations, incentives.
    JEL: D84 D83 J33 M52 O15
    Date: 2013–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cep:stieop:46&r=exp
  12. By: Guillén, Pablo; Hing, Alexander
    Abstract: We test the effect of advice on the well known top trading cycles (TTC) matching algorithm in a school choice frame work. We compare three treatments involving third party advice [right advice (R), wrong advice (W), and both right and wrong advice (RW)] to a no-advice baseline (B). In line with previous literature the truth telling rate is higher than 80% in the baseline, but it becomes as low as 35% in the W treatment. Truth telling rates are also significantly lower in R than in B, and much lower in RW than in B. This evidence suggests that a vast majority of participants in our experiment were confused. Truth telling seems to work only as a default strategy, and participants can be heavily influenced by advice. The real life implementation of matching mechanisms may have been misguided by some laboratory experimentation.
    Date: 2013–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:syd:wpaper:2123/9255&r=exp
  13. By: Atalay, Kadir; Bakhtiar, Fayzan; Cheung, Stephen L.; Slonim, Robert
    Abstract: Many households have insufficient savings to handle moderate and routine consumption shocks. Many of these financially-fragile households also have the highest lottery expenditures as a proportion of income. This combination suggests that Prize-Linked Savings (PLS) accounts, combining security of principal with lottery-type jackpots, can increase savings among these at-risk households. Results from an online experiment show that the introduction of PLS accounts increase total savings and reduce lottery expenditures significantly, especially among individuals with the lowest levels of savings and income. The results imply that PLS accounts offer a plausible market-based solution to encourage individuals to increase savings.
    Keywords: Individual Decision Making; Online Experiment; Lotteries; Savings; Personal Finance
    Date: 2013–06
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:syd:wpaper:2123/9259&r=exp
  14. By: Mitesh Kataria (Max Planck Institute of Economics, Strategic Interaction Group,Jena)
    Abstract: Maniadis et al. (2013) present a theoretical framework that aims at providing insights into the mechanics of proper inference. They suggest that a decision about whether to call an experimental finding noteworthy, or deserving of great attention, should be based on the calculated post-study probability. Although I in large agree with most points in Maniadis et al. (2013), this note raises some important caveats.
    Keywords: Bayes' theorem, Methodology
    JEL: C11 C12 C80
    Date: 2013–08–14
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:jrp:jrpwrp:2013-030&r=exp

This nep-exp issue is ©2013 by Daniel Houser. It is provided as is without any express or implied warranty. It may be freely redistributed in whole or in part for any purpose. If distributed in part, please include this notice.
General information on the NEP project can be found at http://nep.repec.org. For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese at <director@nep.repec.org>. Put “NEP” in the subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.