nep-exp New Economics Papers
on Experimental Economics
Issue of 2005‒08‒13
seventeen papers chosen by
Daniel Houser
George Mason University

  1. Giving in Dictator Games: Regard for Others or Regard by Others? By Alexander K. Koch; Hans-Theo Normann
  2. Experimental Evidence for Tax Policy Design By Jorge Martinez-Vazquez; Mark Rider; Lucy F. Ackert; Ann Gillette
  3. Testing for Team Spirit - An Experimental Study By Rupert Sausgruber
  4. Let the Dummy Talk! Unilateral Communication and Discrimination in Three-Person Dictator Experiments By Ben Greiner; Werner Guth; Ro’i Zultan
  5. Effects of Tax Morale on Tax Compliance: Experimental and Survey Evidence By Ronald G. Cummings; Jorge Martinez-Vazquez; Michael McKee; Benno Torgler
  6. Comparison of Mean-Variance Theory and Expected-Utility Theory through a Laboratory Experiment By Andrea Morone
  7. Capital and Labor Effects in a Recall Task: More Evidence in Support of Camerer and Hogarth (1999) By Ondrej Rydval
  8. Ellsberg Revisited: an Experimental Study By Halevy, Yoram
  9. The impact of payoff interdependence on trust and trustworthiness By M. Vittoria Levati; Matteo Ploner; Werner Güth
  10. Did the Devil Make Them Do It? The Effects of Religion and Religiosity in Public Goods and Trust Games By Lisa R. Anderson; Jennifer M. Mellor; Jeffrey Milyo
  11. Fairness and the Optimal Allocation of Ownership Rights By Ernst Fehr; Susanne Kremhelmer; Klaus Schmidt
  12. Competitive Work Environments and Social Preferences: Field experimental evidence from a japanese fishing community By Jeffrey Carpenter; Erika Seki
  13. Do Social Preferences Increase Productivity? Field Experimental Evidence from Fishermen in Toyama Bay By Jeffrey Carpenter; Erika Seki
  14. What's Psychology Worth? A Field Experiment in the Consumer Credit Market By Marianne Bertrand; Dean S. Karlan; Sendhil Mullainathan; Eldar Shafir; Jonathan Zinman
  15. Achieving Compliance when Legal Sanctions are Non-Deterrent By Jean-Robert Tyran; Lars P. Feld
  16. Why Do People Pay Taxes? Prospect Theory Versus Expected Utility Theory By Sanjit Dhami; Ali al-Nowaihi
  17. Incentives and Prosocial Behavior By Roland Bénabou; Jean Tirole

  1. By: Alexander K. Koch (Royal Holloway, University of London and IZA Bonn); Hans-Theo Normann (Royal Holloway, University of London)
    Abstract: Recent bargaining experiments demonstrated an impact of anonymity and incomplete information on subjects' behavior. This has rekindled the question whether "fair" behavior is inspired by regard for others or is explained by external forces. To test for the importance of external pressure we compare a standard double blind dictator game to a treatment which provides no information about the source of dictator offers, and where recipients do not even know that they participate in an experiment. We find no differences between treatments. This suggests that those dictators who give are purely internally motivated, as asserted by models of other-regarding preferences.
    Keywords: dictator game, altruism, social preferences
    JEL: A13 C91 D64
    Date: 2005–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp1703&r=exp
  2. By: Jorge Martinez-Vazquez (Andrew Young School of Policy Studies); Mark Rider (Andrew Young School of Policy Studies); Lucy F. Ackert (Kennesaw State University); Ann Gillette (Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta)
    Abstract: There is considerable evidence that enforcement efforts can increase tax compliance. However, there must be other forces at work because observed compliance levels cannot be fully explained by the level of enforcement actions typical of most tax authorities. Further, there are observed differences, not related to enforcement effort, in the levels of compliance across countries and cultures. To fully understand differences in compliance behavior across cultures one needs to understand differences in tax administration and citizen attitudes toward governments. The working hypothesis is that cross-cultural differences in behavior have foundations in these institutions. Tax compliance is a complex behavioral issue and its investigation requires the use of a variety of methods and data sources. Results from laboratory experiments conducted in different countries demonstrate that observed differences in tax compliance levels can be explained by differences in the fairness of tax administration, in the perceived fiscal exchange, and in the overall attitude towards the respective governments. These experimental results are shown to be robust by replicating them for the same countries using survey response measures of “tax morale.”
    Keywords: Equity, Social preferences, Inequity aversion, Optimal taxation
    Date: 2005–08–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ays:ispwps:paper0517&r=exp
  3. By: Rupert Sausgruber (University of Innsbruck)
    Abstract: It is often suggested that team spirit counteracts free-riding. Testing for team spirit with field data is difficult, however, due to an inherent identification problem. In this paper test for team spirit experimentally. In a team work task we vary subjects' information about relative team performance while we leave unchanged the structure of explicit incentives. We find that subjects contribute more to their team's project when teams observe each others' performance. We attribute this result to the enhancement of team spirit caused by asymmetric peer effects between observing teams.
    Keywords: team spirit, peer effects, organization of work, public goods experiments
    JEL: C92 H41 J2
    Date: 2005–08–02
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:wpa:wuwpex:0508001&r=exp
  4. By: Ben Greiner; Werner Guth; Ro’i Zultan
    Abstract: To explain why pre-play communication increases cooperation in games, one refers to a) strategic causes such as efficient communication or reputation effects, and b) changes in the utilities due to social processes. Hitherto experimental support for both explanations is mixed and confounded. Our experimental design eliminates all strategic factors and allows to focus on the effects of communication processes. We clearly find social effects, but none of revealed anonymity or salient communication. The social processes invoked are very heterogeneous but not irregular for different communicators.
    Keywords: bargaining; communication; social utility; n-persons dictator game
    JEL: C72 C91 D64
    Date: 2005–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:huj:dispap:dp396&r=exp
  5. By: Ronald G. Cummings (Andrew Young School of Policy Studies); Jorge Martinez-Vazquez (Andrew Young School of Policy Studies); Michael McKee; Benno Torgler (World Bank)
    Abstract: There is considerable evidence that enforcement efforts can increase tax compliance. However, there must be other forces at work because observed compliance levels cannot be fully explained by the level of enforcement actions typical of most tax authorities. Further, there are observed differences, not related to enforcement effort, in the levels of compliance across countries and cultures. To fully understand differences in compliance behavior across cultures one needs to understand differences in tax administration and citizen attitudes toward governments. The working hypothesis is that cross-cultural differences in behavior have foundations in these institutions. Tax compliance is a complex behavioral issue and its investigation requires the use of a variety of methods and data sources. Results from laboratory experiments conducted in different countries demonstrate that observed differences in tax compliance levels can be explained by differences in the fairness of tax administration, in the perceived fiscal exchange, and in the overall attitude towards the respective governments. These experimental results are shown to be robust by replicating them for the same countries using survey response measures of “tax morale.”
    Keywords: Behavior, tax morale, tax compliance
    Date: 2005–07–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ays:ispwps:paper0516&r=exp
  6. By: Andrea Morone
    Abstract: In the 40's and early 50' two decision theories were proposed and have since dominated the scene of the fascinating field of decision-making. In 1944 - when von Neumann and Morgenstern showed that if preferences are consistent with a set of axioms then it is possible to represent these preferences by the expectation of some utility function - Expected Utility theory provides a natural way to establish "measurable utility". In the early 50's Markowitz introduced the Mean-Variance theory that is the basis of modern portfolio selection theory. Even if both models were analyzed from virtually all possible points of view; although they were tested against several generalizations; even though they seem to be the most attractive theories of decision making, they were never tested against each other. This paper will try to fill this gap. It investigates, using experimental data, which of these two models represent a better approximation of subjects' preferences.
    Keywords: Expected utility, Mean variance, preference functional, pair wise choice, experiments.
    JEL: C92 G12
    Date: 2005–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:esi:discus:2005-20&r=exp
  7. By: Ondrej Rydval
    Abstract: This paper extends existing evidence on the interaction and relative productivity of cognitive effort and cognitive capital in an experimental environment. I focus on the impact of task-specific cognitive capital, which is central to the capital-labor argument of Camerer and Hogarth (1999) as well as related research in cognitive science and behavioral decision making. Using a memory recall task situated in an accounting setting, I show that the impact of taskspecific accounting knowledge on recall performance varies with the timing of the introduction of performance-contingent financial incentives. I further illustrate that subjects better endowed with task-specific accounting knowledge greater improve recall performance in response to the introduction of performance-contingent financial incentives. I draw implications for further research of the capital-labor-production framework and for compensation practices in experiments as well as work settings.
    Keywords: Financial incentives, Cognitive abilities, Experiments, Field experiments.
    JEL: C81 C91 C93 D83
    Date: 2005–06
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cer:papers:wp264&r=exp
  8. By: Halevy, Yoram
    Abstract: An extension to Ellsberg's experiment demonstrates that attitudes to ambiguity and compound objective lotteries are tightly associated. The sample is decomposed into three main groups: subjective expected utility subjects - who reduce compound objective lotteries and are ambiguity neutral, and two groups that exhibit different forms of association between preferences over compound lotteries and ambiguity - corresponding to alternative theoretical models that account for ambiguity averse or seeking behavior.
    JEL: D81 C91
    Date: 2005–07–26
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ubc:pmicro:halevy-05-07-26-11-51-13&r=exp
  9. By: M. Vittoria Levati; Matteo Ploner; Werner Güth
    Abstract: In one-shot investment game experiments where each player's payoff is a convex combination of own and other's profit, trust remains unaffected by the extent of interdependence whereas trustworthiness reacts positively to it.
    Keywords: Investment game; Trust; Trustworthiness; Payoff interdependence
    JEL: C72 C92 D62
    Date: 2005–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:esi:discus:2005-19&r=exp
  10. By: Lisa R. Anderson (Department of Economics, College of William and Mary); Jennifer M. Mellor (Department of Economics, College of William and Mary); Jeffrey Milyo (Department of Economics and Truman School of Public Affairs, University of Missouri)
    Abstract: We test whether religious affiliation and participation in religious services are associated with behavior in public goods and trust games. Overall, religious affiliation is unrelated to individual behavior. However, we find some weak evidence that among subjects attending religious services, increased participation is associated with behavior in both public goods and trust games.
    Keywords: public goods experiment, trust, religion
    JEL: C9 H4 Z12
    Date: 2005–08–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cwm:wpaper:20&r=exp
  11. By: Ernst Fehr; Susanne Kremhelmer; Klaus Schmidt
    Abstract: We report on several experiments on the optimal allocation of ownership rights. The experiments confirm the property rights approach by showing that the ownership structure affects relationship-specific investments and that subjects attain the most efficient ownership allocation despite starting from different initial conditions. However, in contrast to the property rights approach, the most efficient ownership structure is joint ownership. These results are neither consistent with the self-interest model nor with models that assume that all people behave fairly, but they can be explained by the theory of inequity aversion that focuses on the interaction between selfish and fair players.
    Keywords: ownership rights, double moral hazard, fairness, reciprocity, incomplete contracts
    JEL: C70 C90 J30
    Date: 2005
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ces:ceswps:_1467&r=exp
  12. By: Jeffrey Carpenter; Erika Seki
    Abstract: Models of job tournaments and competitive workplaces more generally predict that while individual effort may increase as competition intensifies between workers, the incentive for workers to cooperate with each other diminishes. We report on a field experiment conducted with workers from a fishing community in Toyama Bay, Japan. Our participants are employed in three different aspects of fishing. The first group are fishermen, the second group are fish wholesalers (or traders), and the third group are staff at the local fishing coop. Although our participants have much in common (e.g., their common relationship to the local fishery and the fact that they all live in the same community), we argue that they are exposed to different amounts of competition on-the-job and that these differences explain differences in cooperation in our experiment. Specifically, fisherman and traders, who interact in more competitive environments are significantly less cooperative than coop staff who face little competition on the job. Further, after accounting for the possibility of personality-based selection, perceptions of competition faced on-the-job and the treatment effect of job incentives explain these difference in cooperation to a large extent.
    Keywords: Field experiment, cooperation, social disapproval, social preference, competition, Japan, fishing
    JEL: C90 C93 H41 M54 Z13
    Date: 2005
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:mdl:mdlpap:0513&r=exp
  13. By: Jeffrey Carpenter (Middlebury College and IZA Bonn); Erika Seki (University of Aberdeen)
    Abstract: We provide a reason for the wider economics profession to take social preferences, a concern for the outcomes achieved by other reference agents, seriously. Although we show that student measures of social preference elicited in an experiment have little external validity when compared to measures obtained from a field experiment with a population of participants who face a social dilemma in their daily lives (i.e., team production), we do find strong links between the social preferences of our field participants and their productivity at work. We also find that the stock of social preferences evolves endogeously with respect to how widely team production is utilized.
    Keywords: field experiment, social preference, income pooling, productivity
    JEL: C93 D21 D24 H41 J24 M52 M54 Z13
    Date: 2005–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp1697&r=exp
  14. By: Marianne Bertrand (University of Chicago, NBER & CEPR); Dean S. Karlan (Yale University, Economic Growth Center); Sendhil Mullainathan (Harvard University & NBER); Eldar Shafir (Princeton University); Jonathan Zinman (Dartmouth College)
    Abstract: Numerous laboratory studies report on behaviors inconsistent with rational economic models. How much do these inconsistencies matter in natural settings, when consumers make large, real decisions and have the opportunity to learn from experiences? We report on a field experiment designed to address this question. Incumbent clients of a lender in South Africa were sent letters offering them large, short-term loans at randomly chosen interest rates. Psychological “features” on the letter, which did not affect offer terms or economic content, were also independently randomized. Consistent with standard economics, the interest rate significantly affected loan take-up. Inconsistent with standard economics, the psychological features also significantly affected take-up. The independent randomizations allow us to quantify the relative importance of psychological features and prices. Our core finding is the sheer magnitude of the psychological effects. On average, any one psychological manipulation has the same effect as a one half percentage point change in the monthly interest rate. Interestingly, the psychological features appear to have greater impact in the context of less advantageous offers. Moreover, the psychological features do not appear to draw in marginally worse clients, nor does the magnitude of the psychological effects vary systematically with income or education. In short, even in a market setting with large stakes and experienced customers, subtle psychological features that normatively ought to have no impact appear to be extremely powerful drivers of behavior.
    Keywords: Behavioral economics, psychology, microfinance, marketing, field experiment, credit markets
    JEL: C93 D12 D21 D81 D91 M37 O12
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:egc:wpaper:918&r=exp
  15. By: Jean-Robert Tyran; Lars P. Feld
    Abstract: Law backed by non-deterrent sanctions (mild law) has been hypothesized to achieve compliance because of norm activation. We experimentally investigate the effects of mild law in the provision of public goods by comparing it to severe law (deterrent sanctions) and no law. The results show that exogenously imposing mild law does not achieve compliance, but compliance is much improved if mild law is endogenously chosen, i.e. self-imposed. We show that voting for mild law induces expectations of cooperation, and that people tend to comply with the law if they expect many others to do so.
    Keywords: Deterrent effect of legal sanctions; Expressive law; Social norms; Public goods; Voting
    JEL: C92 D72 K42
    Date: 2005–02
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cra:wpaper:2005-17&r=exp
  16. By: Sanjit Dhami; Ali al-Nowaihi
    Abstract: Given actual probabilities of audit and penalty rates observed in the real world, tax evasion should be an extremely attractive gamble to an expected utility maximizer. However, in practice, one observes too much compliance relative to the predictions of expected utility. This paper considers an alternative theoretical model that is based on Kahneman and Tversky’s cumulative prospect theory. The model predicts empirically plausible magnitudes of tax evasion despite low audit probabilities and penalty rates. An increase in the tax rate leads to an increase in the amount evaded- a result, which is in broad agreement with the evidence, but is contrary to the prediction made by expected utility theory. Furthermore, we show that the optimal tax rates predicted by prospect theory, in the presence of tax evasion behaviour, are consistent with actual tax rates.
    Keywords: Reference Dependence; Loss Aversion; Decision Weights; Prospect Theory; Expected Utility Theory; Tax Evasion; Optimal taxation
    JEL: D81 H26 K42
    Date: 2005–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:lec:leecon:05/23&r=exp
  17. By: Roland Bénabou (Princeton University, CEPR, NBER and IZA Bonn); Jean Tirole (Institut d’Economie Industrielle (IDEI), GREMAQ, CERAS and MIT)
    Abstract: We develop a theory of prosocial behavior that combines heterogeneity in individual altruism and greed with concerns for social reputation or self-respect. Rewards or punishments (whether material or image-related) create doubt about the true motive for which good deeds are performed and this "overjustification effect" can induce a partial or even net crowding out of prosocial behavior by extrinsic incentives. We also identify settings that are conducive to multiple social norms and those where disclosing one’s generosity may backfire. Finally, we analyze the choice by public and private sponsors of incentive levels, their degree of confidentiality and the publicity given to agents’ behavior. Sponsor competition is shown to potentially reduce social welfare.
    Keywords: altruism, rewards, motivation, esteem, crowding out, overjustification effect, identity, social norms, morals, greed, psychology
    JEL: D64 D82 H41 Z13
    Date: 2005–07
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp1695&r=exp

This nep-exp issue is ©2005 by Daniel Houser. It is provided as is without any express or implied warranty. It may be freely redistributed in whole or in part for any purpose. If distributed in part, please include this notice.
General information on the NEP project can be found at http://nep.repec.org. For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese at <director@nep.repec.org>. Put “NEP” in the subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.