nep-evo New Economics Papers
on Evolutionary Economics
Issue of 2013‒02‒08
nine papers chosen by
Matthew Baker
City University of New York

  1. Experimental Study of Bilateral Cooperation Under a Political Conflict: The Case of Israelis and Palestinians By Sebastian J. Goerg; Jan Meise; Gari Walkowitz; Eyal Winter
  2. An Eye-Tracking Study of Feature-Based Choice in One-Shot Games By Giovanna Devetag; Sibilla Di Guida; Luca Polonio
  3. Overbidding and Heterogeneous Behavior in Contest Experiments By Sheremeta, Roman
  4. Cultural Evolution, Economic Growth and Human Welfare - A Drift Process? By Ulrich Witt
  5. The Importance of Being Marginal: Gender Differences in Generosity By Stefano DellaVigna; John A. List; Ulrike Malmendier; Gautam Rao
  6. The Origins of Social Contracts: Attitudes toward Taxation in Urban Nigeria. By Cristina Bodea; Adrienne LeBas
  7. Multi-profile intertemporal social choice: a survey By Bossert, Walter; Suzumura, Kotaro
  8. Manipulating Reliance on Intuition Reduces Risk and Ambiguity Aversion By Jeffrey V. Butler; Luigi Guiso; Tullio Jappelli
  9. I’ll do it by myself as I knew it all along’: On the failure of hindsight-biased principals to delegate optimally By David Danz; Frank Hüber; Dorothea Kübler; Lydia Mechtenberg; Julia Schmid

  1. By: Sebastian J. Goerg; Jan Meise; Gari Walkowitz; Eyal Winter
    Abstract: We investigate strategic interactions of Israelis and Palestinians within a controlled laboratory experiment. In our first treatment we retrieve cooperation benchmarks prevailing within both subject pools. Then we measure cooperation levels and associated beliefs between Israelis and Palestinians. Treatment three assesses the influence of pre-play face-to-face encounter on cooperative behavior. Our findings are: The degree of expected and actual cooperation within the Palestinian subject pool is significantly higher as compared to the respective levels found in Israel. In line with previous findings, cooperation decreases if subjects are paired with subjects from the other subject pool. Previously detected subject pool differences are not offset. The drop in inter-subject pool cooperation can be outweighed by the introducing of face-to-face communication, which dramatically increases the cooperation rates. The differences in contributions between Palestinians and Israelis are associated with differences in subjects' beliefs. Face-to-face encounter increases and balances beliefs and therefore enhances cooperation.
    Keywords: Bargaining, Belief-structure, Israeli-Palestinian Conflict, International Cooperation, Prisoner's Dilemma
    JEL: A13 C72 C91 F51
    Date: 2013–01–21
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cgr:cgsser:04-01&r=evo
  2. By: Giovanna Devetag; Sibilla Di Guida; Luca Polonio
    Abstract: We analyze subjects’ eye movements while they make decisions in a series of one-shot games. The majority of them perform a partial and selective analysis of the payoff matrix, often ignoring the payoffs of the opponent and/or paying attention only to specific cells. Our results suggest that subjects apply boundedly rational decision heuristics that involve best responding to a simplification of the decision problem, obtained either by ignoring the other players’ motivations or by considering them only for a subset of outcomes. Finally, we find a correlation between types of eye movements observed and choices in the games.
    Keywords: one-shot games; eye-tracking; similarity; categorization; focal points; experimental economics; individual behavior; behavioral economics
    JEL: C72 C91 D01 D83
    Date: 2013–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:eca:wpaper:2013/138438&r=evo
  3. By: Sheremeta, Roman
    Abstract: We provide an overview of experimental literature on contests and point out the two main phenomena observed in most contest experiments: (i) overbidding relative to the standard Nash equilibrium prediction and (ii) heterogeneous behavior of ex-ante symmetric contestants. Based on the sample of contest experiments that we review, the median overbidding rate is 72%. We provide different explanations for the overbidding phenomenon, including bounded rationality, utility of winning, other-regarding preferences, probability distortion, and the shape of the payoff function. We also provide explanations for heterogeneous behavior of contestants based on differences in preferences towards winning, inequality, risk and losses, and demographic differences. Furthermore, we suggest mechanisms that can reduce overbidding and induce more homogeneous behavior. Finally, we discuss directions for future research.
    Keywords: experiments; contests; overbidding; heterogeneous behavior
    JEL: C92 D74 D72 C91 C72
    Date: 2013–01–25
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:44124&r=evo
  4. By: Ulrich Witt
    Abstract: To assess whether and when the equation "economic growth = better life" holds, it is necessary to understand what human motivations drive the economic growth process. The preference subjectivism of canonical welfare economics is of little help here as it treats the motivations underlying individual behavior as an unexplained "black box". The present paper therefore reviews several motivational hypotheses suggested by biology, behavioral science, and cognitive psychology. They point to a strong influence of cognitive and noncognitive learning processes on the underlying motivations or, in economic terminology, the emergence and change of individual preferences. As a consequence, subjective welfare assessments tend to follow a drift process once a certain level of prosperity has been accomplished by economic growth. The normative relevance of the resulting preference relativism is argued to be particularly momentous, if the value basis of normative judgments is extended beyond the welfare criterion to justice and fairness considerations.
    Date: 2013–01–31
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:esi:evopap:2012-20&r=evo
  5. By: Stefano DellaVigna; John A. List; Ulrike Malmendier; Gautam Rao
    Abstract: Do men and women have different social preferences? Previous findings are contradictory. We provide a potential explanation using evidence from a field experiment. In a door-to-door solicitation, men and women are equally generous, but women become less generous when it becomes easy to avoid the solicitor. Our structural estimates of the social preference parameters suggest an explanation: women are more likely to be on the margin of giving, partly because of a less dispersed distribution of altruism. We find similar results for the willingness to complete an unpaid survey: women are more likely to be on the margin of participation.
    JEL: C93 D64 H4
    Date: 2013–02
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:18748&r=evo
  6. By: Cristina Bodea; Adrienne LeBas
    Abstract: How do social contracts come into being? This paper argues that norm adoption plays an important and neglected role in this process. Using novel data from urban Nigeria, we examine why individuals adopt norms favoring a citizen obligation to pay tax where state enforcement is weak. We find that public goods delivery by the state produces the willingness to pay tax, but community characteristics also have a strong and independent effect on both social contract norms and actual tax payment. Individuals are less likely to adopt pro-tax norms if they have access to community provision of security and other services. In conflict-prone communities, where “self-help” provision of club goods is less effective, individuals are more likely to adopt social contract norms. Finally, we show that social contract norms substantially boost tax payment. This paper has broad implications for literatures on state formation, taxation, clientelism, and public goods provision.
    Date: 2013
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:csa:wpaper:2013/02&r=evo
  7. By: Bossert, Walter; Suzumura, Kotaro
    Abstract: We provide a brief survey of some literature on intertemporal social choice theory in a multi-profile setting. As is well-known, Arrow’s impossibility result hinges on the assumption that the population is finite. For infinite populations, there exist nondictatorial social welfare functions satisfying Arrow’s axioms and they can be described by their corresponding collections of decisive coalitions. We review contributions that explore whether this possibility in the infinite-population context allows for a richer class of social welfare functions in an intergenerational model. Different notions of stationarity formulated for individual and for social preferences are examined.
    Keywords: Infinite-population social choice, multi-profile social choice, decisiveness, intergenerational choice
    JEL: D71
    Date: 2013–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hit:cisdps:584&r=evo
  8. By: Jeffrey V. Butler (EIEF); Luigi Guiso (EIEF); Tullio Jappelli (University of Naples "Federico II" and CSEF)
    Abstract: Prior research suggests that those who rely on intuition rather than effortful reasoning when making decisions are less averse to risk and ambiguity. The evidence is largely correlational, however, leaving open the question of the direction of causality. In this paper, we present experimental evidence of causation running from reliance on intuition to risk and ambiguity preferences. We directly manipulate participants’ predilection to rely on intuition and find that enhancing reliance on intuition lowers the probability of being ambiguity averse by 30 percentage points and increases risk tolerance by about 30 percent in the experimental subpopulation where we would a priori expect the manipulation to be successful (males).
    Date: 2013
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:eie:wpaper:1301&r=evo
  9. By: David Danz; Frank Hüber; Dorothea Kübler; Lydia Mechtenberg; Julia Schmid
    Abstract: With the help of a simple model, we show that the hindsight bias can lead to ineffcient delegation decisions. This prediction is tested experimentally. In an online experiment that was conducted during the FIFA World Cup 2010 participants were asked to predict a number of outcomes of the ongoing World Cup and had to recall their assessments after the outcomes had been realized. This served as a measure of the hindsight bias for each participant. The participants also had to make choices in a delegation game. Our data confirm that hindsight-biased subjects more frequently fail to delegate optimally than subjects whom we have classified as not hindsight biased.
    Keywords: hindsight bias, delegation, experiments
    JEL: C72 C91 D84
    Date: 2013–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hum:wpaper:sfb649dp2013-009&r=evo

This nep-evo issue is ©2013 by Matthew Baker. It is provided as is without any express or implied warranty. It may be freely redistributed in whole or in part for any purpose. If distributed in part, please include this notice.
General information on the NEP project can be found at http://nep.repec.org. For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese at <director@nep.repec.org>. Put “NEP” in the subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.