nep-cna New Economics Papers
on China
Issue of 2021‒08‒30
seven papers chosen by
Zheng Fang
Ohio State University

  1. Child Education-Induced Migration and Its Impact on the Economic Behaviors of Migrated Households in China By Yan, Weibo; Nie, Peng
  2. Financing Entrepreneurship and Innovation in China By Lin William Cong; Charles M. C. Lee; Yuanyu Qu; Tao Shen
  3. Import Competition and Informal Employment: Empirical Evidence from China By Wang, Feicheng; Liang, Zhe; Lehmann, Hartmut
  4. China’s Energy Law Draft and the Reform of its Electricity Supply Sector By Jun Xu; Michael Pollitt; Bai-Chen Xie; Chun-Han Yang
  5. Digital payments in China: adoption and interactions among applications By Dominique Torre; Qing Xu
  6. Forecasting Urban Residential Stock Turnover Dynamics using System Dynamics and Bayesian Model Averaging By Wei Zhou; Eoghan O’Neill; Alice Moncaster; David Reiner; Peter Guthrie
  7. Income and Wealth Inequality in Hong Kong, 1981-2020: The Rise of Pluto-Communism? By Thomas Piketty; Li Yang

  1. By: Yan, Weibo (Zhongnan University of Economics and Law); Nie, Peng (Xi’an Jiaotong University)
    Abstract: Using the 2011-2013 China Migrants Dynamic Survey, this paper utilizes the quarter of the year in which a child was born as an instrumental variable to measure child education shock and explores its impact on migrated households. We only find significant education-induced migration among boys, which we attribute to son preference in China. Due to child education-induced migration, the per capita household consumption increases by 56.7%, the savings rate decreases by 40.3%, and remittances sent home decline by about 1.3 monthly household incomes, however, there are no effects on income, food consumption, and house rent. After exploring the mechanisms underlying child education-induced migration, we find that children migrate with their parents for a better education in urban areas. Because of the closure and consolidation of rural primary schools, children are forced to migrate due to their education needs. The accessibility of primary schools in urban areas is also responsible for migration decisions regarding children. This paper facilitates understanding of how Hukou influences gender inequality in China. We also provide evidence to show that the segregation of the education system through Hukou is a possible explanation for the low consumption rate of migrants.
    Keywords: education-induced migration, Hukou, son preference, economic behaviors
    JEL: O15 I28 D14
    Date: 2021–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp14653&r=
  2. By: Lin William Cong; Charles M. C. Lee; Yuanyu Qu; Tao Shen
    Abstract: This study reports on the current state-of-affairs in the funding of entrepreneurship and innovations in China and provides a broad survey of academic findings on the subject. We also discuss the implications of these findings for public policies governing the Chinese financial system, particularly regulations governing the initial public offering (IPO) process. We also identify and discuss promising areas for future research.
    Date: 2021–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:arx:papers:2108.10982&r=
  3. By: Wang, Feicheng (University of Göttingen); Liang, Zhe (University of Nottingham); Lehmann, Hartmut (Leibniz Institute for East and Southeast European Studies (IOS))
    Abstract: This paper investigates the effects of trade liberalisation induced labour demand shocks on informal employment in China. We employ a local labour market approach to construct a regional measure of exposure to import tariffs by exploiting initial differences in industrial composition across prefectural cities and then link it with the employment status of individuals. Using three waves of household survey data between 1995 and 2007, our results show that workers from regions that experienced a larger tariff cut were more likely to be employed informally. Further results based on firm-level data reveal a consistent pattern; tariff reductions increased the share of informal workers within firms. Such effects are more salient among smaller and less productive firms. Our findings suggest an important margin of labour market adjustment in response to trade shocks in developing countries, i.e. employment adjustment along the formal-informal dimension.
    Keywords: trade liberalisation, import competition, informal employment, firms, China
    JEL: F14 F16 F66 J46
    Date: 2021–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp14650&r=
  4. By: Jun Xu (Zhejiang University of Finance and Economics, China); Michael Pollitt (EPRG, CJBS, University of Cambridge); Bai-Chen Xie (College of Management and Economics, Tianjin University, China); Chun-Han Yang (University of Oxford)
    Keywords: No.9 Document, Energy Law, power market reform
    JEL: K32
    Date: 2020–09
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:enp:wpaper:eprg2028&r=
  5. By: Dominique Torre (GREDEG - Groupe de Recherche en Droit, Economie et Gestion - UNS - Université Nice Sophia Antipolis (... - 2019) - COMUE UCA - COMUE Université Côte d'Azur (2015 - 2019) - CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique - UCA - Université Côte d'Azur); Qing Xu (GREDEG - Groupe de Recherche en Droit, Economie et Gestion - UNS - Université Nice Sophia Antipolis (... - 2019) - COMUE UCA - COMUE Université Côte d'Azur (2015 - 2019) - CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique - UCA - Université Côte d'Azur)
    Abstract: Alipay and WeChat Pay, the mobile payment services of Alibaba and Tencent, rapidly spread out in China from the early 2010s. Their successes motivate three open questions: (i) why the two companies did not really compete to gain the exclusivity of their clients? (ii) why the installed basis of the incumbent did not prevent the success of the entrant? (iii) why the new entry accelerated the dffusion of the incumbent's solutions? This paper elaborates an adoption model which encapsulates the distinctive features of the two service providers. It points out that complementaries between the two solutions (dfferentiated services offered to clients, decreasing adoption costs and contrasting business models) can explain the interest of both service providers to avoid any strong competition. During the adoption phase, Alipay and WeChat had interest to a mutual development as soon as they did not offered the same product, with the same business model. In this situation, every improvement of the technology of each operator increased the profit of the other. This strategic complementarity effect between the two competitors could however decrease during time their incentive to innovate.
    Keywords: strategic complementarities,online payment,electronic wallets,payments in China,mobile-payment,paiement mobile,complémentarités stratégiques,paiement en ligne,porte-monnaie électronique,paiements en Chine
    Date: 2020
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hal:journl:halshs-03313693&r=
  6. By: Wei Zhou (Department of Engineering, University of Cambridge); Eoghan O’Neill (Faculty of Economics, University of Cambridge); Alice Moncaster (Department of Engineering, University of Cambridge); David Reiner (EPRG, CJBS, University of Cambridge); Peter Guthrie (Department of Engineering, University of Cambridge)
    Keywords: building stock, lifetime distribution, System Dynamics, Bayesian Model Averaging, Markov Chain Monte Carlo, embodied energy, operational energy, China
    JEL: C11 O18 R21
    Date: 2020–06
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:enp:wpaper:eprg2016&r=
  7. By: Thomas Piketty (PSE - Paris School of Economics - ENPC - École des Ponts ParisTech - ENS Paris - École normale supérieure - Paris - PSL - Université Paris sciences et lettres - UP1 - Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne - CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique - EHESS - École des hautes études en sciences sociales - INRAE - Institut National de Recherche pour l’Agriculture, l’Alimentation et l’Environnement, PJSE - Paris Jourdan Sciences Economiques - UP1 - Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne - ENS Paris - École normale supérieure - Paris - PSL - Université Paris sciences et lettres - EHESS - École des hautes études en sciences sociales - ENPC - École des Ponts ParisTech - CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique - INRAE - Institut National de Recherche pour l’Agriculture, l’Alimentation et l’Environnement, WIL - World Inequality Lab); Li Yang (PSE - Paris School of Economics - ENPC - École des Ponts ParisTech - ENS Paris - École normale supérieure - Paris - PSL - Université Paris sciences et lettres - UP1 - Université Paris 1 Panthéon-Sorbonne - CNRS - Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique - EHESS - École des hautes études en sciences sociales - INRAE - Institut National de Recherche pour l’Agriculture, l’Alimentation et l’Environnement, INSEAD - Institut Européen d'administration des Affaires)
    Abstract: This paper combines national accounts, household surveys, fiscal data, wealth rankings and election polls, in order to provide a comprehensive analysis of the evolution of income and wealth inequality in Hong Kong, as well as its impact on political cleavages over the 1981-2020 period. We find a very large rise in wage inequality since 1981, especially since the Handover of Hong Kong to China. Top 1% earners now receive a much larger fraction of the total wage bill than bottom 50% earners, while the opposite was true in pre-Handover Hong Kong. We also observe an enormous increase in the capital share and the top wealth share (normalized by national income) since 2000. Today Hong Kong's very top wealth share (top 0.001%) is ranked at very top in the world. Finally, we find that the top income earners and high-income professions (such as executives and managers) are more likely to vote for pro-Beijing camp, while the bottom 85% income group, students and lower-income professionals are more likely to be pro-democratic.
    Date: 2021–06
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hal:wilwps:halshs-03321889&r=

This nep-cna issue is ©2021 by Zheng Fang. It is provided as is without any express or implied warranty. It may be freely redistributed in whole or in part for any purpose. If distributed in part, please include this notice.
General information on the NEP project can be found at http://nep.repec.org. For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese at <director@nep.repec.org>. Put “NEP” in the subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.