nep-cna New Economics Papers
on China
Issue of 2008‒12‒07
eight papers chosen by
Zheng Fang
Ohio State University

  1. Learning and sharing in a Chinese high-technology cluster: A study of inter-firm and intra-firm knowledge flows between R&D employees By Matias Ramirez; Xibao Li
  2. China's Renminbi Currency Logistics Network: A Brief Introduction By Smith, Reginald
  3. Exporting deflation? Chinese exports and Japanese prices By David Weinstein; Christian Broda
  4. China's exporters and importers: firms, products, and trade partners By Kalina Manova; Zhiwei Zhang
  5. How do Heterogeneous Social Interactions affect the Peer Effect in Rural–Urban Migration?:Empirical Evidence from China By Zhao Chen; Shiqing Jiang; Ming Lu; Hiroshi Sato
  6. Happiness in the dual society of urban China:Hukou identity, horizontal inequality and heterogeneous reference By Shiqing Jiang; Ming Lu; Hiroshi Sato
  7. Rank, Income and Income Inequality in Urban China By Gustafsson, Björn; Sai, Ding
  8. Testing for Service-Led and Investment-Led Hypothesis: Evidence from ‘Chindia’ By Baharom, A.H.; Habibullah, M.S.

  1. By: Matias Ramirez (SPRU, University of Sussex); Xibao Li (School of Economics & Management, Tsinghua University)
    Keywords: learning, China, knowledge work, knowledge transfer
    JEL: D83 J24
    Date: 2008–01–09
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:sru:ssewps:174&r=cna
  2. By: Smith, Reginald
    Abstract: Currency logistics is becoming a field of increasing interest and importance both in government and academic circles. In this paper, a basic description of China's nationwide logistics network for the Renminbi is discussed and analyzed. In addition to its basic structure, its key problems such as production costs, inventory levels, and transportation and storage security are discussed.
    Keywords: currency; logistics; China; money supply
    JEL: E42 E58
    Date: 2008–11–30
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:11842&r=cna
  3. By: David Weinstein; Christian Broda
    Abstract: Between 1992 and 2002, the Japanese Import Price Index (IPI) registered a decline of almost 9 percent and Japan entered a period of deflation. We show that much of the correlation between import prices and domestic prices was due to formula biases. Had the IPI been computed using a pure Laspeyres index like the CPI, the IPI would have hardly moved at all. A Laspeyres version of the IPI would have risen 1 percentage point per year faster than the official index. Second we show that Chinese prices did not behave differently from the prices of other importers. Although Chinese prices are substantially lower than the prices of other exporters, they do not exhibit a differential trend. However, we estimate that the typical price per unit quality of a Chinese exporter fell by half between 1992 and 2005. Thus the explosive growth in Chinese exports is attributable to growth in the quality of Chinese exports and the increase in new products being exported by China.
    Date: 2008
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:fip:fedfwp:2008-29&r=cna
  4. By: Kalina Manova; Zhiwei Zhang
    Abstract: This paper provides a detailed overview of China's participation in international trade using newly available data on the universe of globally engaged Chinese firms over the 2003-2005 period. We document the distribution of trade flows and product- and trade-partner intensity across both exporting and importing firms and study the relationship between firms' intensive and extensive margins of trade. We also compare trade patterns across firms of different organizational structure, distinguishing between domestic private firms, domestic state-owned firms, foreign-owned firms, and joint ventures. We explore the variation in foreign ownership across sectors, and find results consistent with recent theoretical and empirical work on the role of credit constraints and contractual imperfections in international trade and investment. Finally, we examine the rapid expansion of China's trade over the 2003-2005 period, and decompose it into its extensive and intensive margins. We also use monthly data and study the frequent churning and reallocation of trade flows across firms and across products and trade partners within firms.
    Date: 2008
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:fip:fedfwp:2008-28&r=cna
  5. By: Zhao Chen; Shiqing Jiang; Ming Lu; Hiroshi Sato
    Abstract: In this paper, we use the “2002 Chinese Household Income Project Survey” (CHIPS2002) data to examine how heterogeneous social interactions affect the peer effect in the rural–urban migration decision in China. We find that the peer effect, measured by the village migration ratio, significantly increases the individual probability of outward migration. We also find that the magnitude of the peer effect is nonlinear, depending on the strength and type of social interactions with other villagers. Interactions in information sharing can increase the magnitude of the peer effect, while interactions in mutual help in labor activities, such as help in housing construction, nursing and farm work in busy seasons, will impede the positive role of the peer effect. Being aware of the simultaneity bias caused by the two-way causality between social interaction strengths and migration, we utilize “historical family political identity in land reform” as an instrumental variable for social interactions. However, the hypothesis that probit and instrumental-variable probit results are not significantly different is not rejected. The existence of a nonlinear peer effect has rich policy implications. For policy makers to encourage rural–urban migration, it is feasible to increase education investment in rural areas or increase information sharing among rural residents. However, only an increase in the constant term in the regression, i.e. a “big push” in improving institutions for migration, can help rural Chinese residents escape the low equilibrium in migration.
    Keywords: labor migration, urbanization, peer effect, social integration, social multiplier
    JEL: J61 O15 R23
    Date: 2008
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:lic:licosd:22408&r=cna
  6. By: Shiqing Jiang; Ming Lu; Hiroshi Sato
    Abstract: This paper studies the impact of income inequality on the subjective well-being of different social groups in urban China. We classify urban social groups according to their hukou status: rural migrants, “born” urban residents, and “acquired” urban residents who once changed their hukou identity from rural to urban. We focus on how the horizontal inequality—income disparity between migrants and urban residents—affects individual happiness. The main results are as follows. First, migrants suffer from unhappiness when the horizontal inequality increases, but urban residents show a much smaller aversion to the horizontal inequality. Second, migrants will not be happier if their relative incomes within their migrant group increase, while urban residents do become happier when their incomes increase within their group’s income distribution. Third, “acquired” urban residents have traits of both migrants and “born” urban residents. They have an aversion to the horizontal inequality like migrants, and they also favor higher relative income among urban residents. Fourth, “born” urban residents have lower happiness scores when they are old. People who are Communist Party members strongly dislike the horizontal inequality. Our findings suggest that migrants, “acquired” urban residents, elderly people and Party members from “born” urban residents are the potential proponents of social integration policies in urban China.
    Keywords: Horizontal inequality, Happiness, Hukou identity, Migration, Social integration; horizontal inequality, happiness, Houku identity, migration, social integration
    JEL: I31 O15 R23
    Date: 2008
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:lic:licosd:22308&r=cna
  7. By: Gustafsson, Björn (Göteborg University); Sai, Ding (Chinese Academy of Social Sciences)
    Abstract: While some workers in China attain senior professional level and senior cadre level status (Chuzhang and above), others attain middle rank including middle rank of professional and cadre (Kezhang). This aspect of the Chinese labor force has attracted surprisingly little attention in the literature, a fact which this paper aims to rectify. We define various segments of the urban population in work-active ages and use data from the Chinese Income Project (CHIP) covering eastern, central and western China for 1995 and 2002. For 2002, persons of high rank make up 3 percent and persons of middle rank make up 14 percent of persons in work-active ages. Factors that affect a person's likelihood of having high or middle rank are investigated by estimating a multinomial probit model. We find that education, age and gender strongly affect the probability of being employed as a worker of high rank. There is relatively little income inequality among workers of high rank as well as among workers of middle rank. Mean income and household wealth per capita of highly-ranked workers developed more favorably than for other segments of the population studied, and personal income is more polarized by segment in 2002 than in 1995. Workers of high rank, and to a lesser degree, workers of middle rank, are among the winners in economic terms while the increasingly large category of non-workers are the losers. Rates of return to education have increased but income function analysis indicates that this provides only a partial explanation for the increased favorable income situation for workers of high and middle ranks.
    Keywords: China, rank, income, income inequality
    JEL: J21 J31 J41 P31
    Date: 2008–11
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp3843&r=cna
  8. By: Baharom, A.H.; Habibullah, M.S.
    Abstract: This study examines the meaningful relationship between economic growth, and service sector contribution and domestic investment in two major Asian economies, namely India and China. Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ARDL) bounds testing procedure is employed to analyze the impact of the selected variables namely (1) contribution by the service sector, (2) (4) domestic investment on economic growth and vice versa. The period of interest is 1960-2005 using annual data. The empirical results demonstrate that for the case of India, there is (1) a unidirectional causality from domestic investment to economic growth and (2) from economic growth to services. As for China, only unidirectional causality from services sector to economic growth is detected, while no meaningful relationship was found between domestic investment and economic growth.
    Keywords: Service-led; investment-led; growth; China; India
    JEL: E22 E01
    Date: 2008–10–17
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:11924&r=cna

This nep-cna issue is ©2008 by Zheng Fang. It is provided as is without any express or implied warranty. It may be freely redistributed in whole or in part for any purpose. If distributed in part, please include this notice.
General information on the NEP project can be found at http://nep.repec.org. For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese at <director@nep.repec.org>. Put “NEP” in the subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.