New Economics Papers
on Collective Decision-Making
Issue of 2014‒03‒15
seventeen papers chosen by
Stan C. Weeber, McNeese State University


  1. On a class of threshold public goods games: With applications to voting and the Kyoto Protocol By Bolle, Friedel
  2. Household Demand for Low Carbon Public Policies: Evidence from California By Matthew J. Holian; Matthew E. Kahn
  3. Conditional Punishment By Kamei, Kenju
  4. Election Fairness and Government Legitimacy in Afghanistan By Eli Berman; Michael Callen; Clark Gibson; James D. Long
  5. Impact of Internal Migration on Political Participation in Turkey By Ali T. Akarca; Aysit Tansel
  6. The Political Coase Theorem: Experimental Evidence By Sebastian Galiani; Gustavo Torrens; Maria Lucia Yanguas
  7. Equilibrium Tax Rates and Income Redistribution: A Laboratory Study By Marina Agranov; Thomas R. Palfrey
  8. Direct democracy and local government efficiency By Asatryan, Zareh; De Witte, Kristof
  9. Legitimacy, Communication and Leadership in the Turnaround Game By Jordi Brandts; David J. Cooper; Roberto A. Weber
  10. The Political Economy of Publicly Provided Private Goods By Dotti, Valerio
  11. A Theory of the Intergenerational Dynamics of Inflation Beliefs and Monetary Institutions By Etienne Farvaque; Alexander Mihailov
  12. Regulation of Public Sector Collective Bargaining in the States By Milla Sanes; John Schmitt
  13. Conflict and segregation in networks: An experiment on the interplay between individual preferences and social influence By Penélope Hernández; Guillem Martínez-Canovas; Manuel Muñoz-Herrera; Lea Ellwardt
  14. Are Justices of the US Supreme Court Islands Unto Themselves? Examining external influences on US Supreme Court rulings in securities cases By J.W. Fedderke and M. Mentoruzzo
  15. PARTISAN POLITICS AND COUNTRY RISK: EVIDENCE FROM THE 2002 BRAZILIAN PRESIDENTIAL ELECTION By JORGE HARGRAVE GONÇALVES DA SILVA
  16. Constitutional Rules and Efficient Policies By Michela Cella; Giovanna Iannantuoni; Elena Manzoni
  17. Disagreement and Learning About Reforms By Binswanger, J.; Oechslin, M.

  1. By: Bolle, Friedel
    Abstract: The launch of a public project requires support from enough members of a group. Members (players) are differently important for the project and have different cost/benefit relations. There are players who profit and players who suffer from the launch of the project. Examples are the Kyoto protocol, voting with different weights (shareholders, the UN with the veto power of the Security Council members), and international scientific or military expeditions. As coordination on one of the usually many pure strategy equilibria is difficult, mixed strategy equilibria are the focus of this investigation. If all players profit from the launch of the project then, despite the unnecessary costs, the requirement of full contributions is a Pareto-improvement to every original threshold. The contribution probabilities of some player types defined by their importance are characterized according to their cost/benefit relations. --
    Keywords: Threshold Public Goods,Provision Point Mechanism,Voting
    JEL: D72 H41
    Date: 2014
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:zbw:euvwdp:345&r=cdm
  2. By: Matthew J. Holian; Matthew E. Kahn
    Abstract: In recent years, Californians have voted on two key pieces of low carbon regulation. The resulting voting patterns provide an opportunity to examine the demand for carbon mitigation efforts. Household voting patterns are found to mirror the voting patterns by the U.S Congress on national carbon legislation. Political liberals and more educated voters favor such regulations while suburbanites tend to oppose such initiatives. Survey responses at the individual level are shown to predict the spatial variation in actual voting patterns and hence convergent validity for results obtained with stated preference data on voting markets.
    JEL: Q54 R41
    Date: 2014–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:19965&r=cdm
  3. By: Kamei, Kenju
    Abstract: We elicit human conditional punishment types by conducting experiments. We find that their punishment decisions to an individual are on average significantly positively proportional to other members’ punishment decisions to that individual.
    Keywords: cooperation, punishment, experiments
    JEL: C91 C92 D70 H41
    Date: 2014–02–28
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:54031&r=cdm
  4. By: Eli Berman; Michael Callen; Clark Gibson; James D. Long
    Abstract: International development agencies invest heavily in institution building in fragile states, including expensive interventions to support democratic elections. Yet little evidence exists on whether elections enhance the domestic legitimacy of governments. Using the random assignment of an innovative election fraud-reducing intervention in Afghanistan, we find that decreasing electoral misconduct improves multiple survey measures of attitudes toward government, including: (1) whether Afghanistan is a democracy; (2) whether the police should resolve disputes; (3) whether members of parliament provide services; and (4) willingness to report insurgent behavior to security forces.
    JEL: H41 O10 O17 O53 P16
    Date: 2014–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:19949&r=cdm
  5. By: Ali T. Akarca (Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Chicago); Aysit Tansel (Department of Economics, METU)
    Abstract: During last sixty years, Turkish population moved from one province to another at the rate of about 7-8 percent per five-year interval. As a consequence of this massive internal migration, population residing in a province other than the one they were born in increased from 12 percent in 1950 to 39 percent in 2011. Impact of this population instability on provincial turnout rates in 2011 parliamentary election is studied, controlling for the effects of other socio-economic, demographic, political and institutional factors. Consequences of migration both at destinations and origins are considered. According to robust regressions estimated, the relationship between turnout and education is inverse U-shaped, and between turnout and age, U-shaped. The latter reflects generational differences as well. Large population, large number parliament members to be elected from a constituency, participation by large number of parties, and existence of a dominant party depress the turnout rate. A percentage increase in the proportion of emigrants among the people born in a province reduces turnout rate in that province by 0.13 percentage points, while a percentage increase in the ratio of immigrants in the population of a province reduces it by 0.06 percentage points. However, at destinations where large numbers of immigrants from different regions are concentrated, the opportunity afforded to immigrants to elect one of their own, reduces the latter adverse impact significantly and in some cases turns it to positive.
    Keywords: election turnout, internal migration, political participation, Turkey, voter behavior.
    JEL: D72 J61
    Date: 2014–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:met:wpaper:1402&r=cdm
  6. By: Sebastian Galiani; Gustavo Torrens; Maria Lucia Yanguas
    Abstract: The Political Coase Theorem (PCT) states that, in the absence of transaction costs, agents should agree to implement efficient policies regardless of the distribution of bargaining power among them. This paper uses a laboratory experiment to explore how commitment problems undermine the validity of the PCT. Overall, the results support theoretical predictions. In particular, commitment issues matter, and the existence of more commitment possibilities leads to better social outcomes. Moreover, we find that the link is valid when commitment possibilities are asymmetrically distributed between players and even when a redistribution of political power is required to take advantage of those possibilities. However, we also find that at low levels of commitment there is more cooperation than strictly predicted by our parameterized model while the opposite is true at high levels of commitment, and only large improvements in commitment opportunities have a significant effect on the social surplus, while small changes do not.
    JEL: C92 D72
    Date: 2014–02
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:19943&r=cdm
  7. By: Marina Agranov; Thomas R. Palfrey
    Abstract: This paper reports results from a laboratory experiment that investigates the Meltzer-Richard model of equilibrium tax rates, inequality, and income redistribution. We also extend that model to incorporate social preferences in the form of altruism and inequality aversion. The experiment varies the amount of inequality and the collective choice procedure to determine tax rates. We report four main findings. First, higher wage inequality leads to higher tax rates. The effect is significant and large in magnitude. Second, the average implemented tax rates are almost exactly equal to the theoretical ideal tax rate of the median wage worker. Third, we do not observe any significant differences in labor supply or average implemented tax rates between a direct democracy institution and a representative democracy system where tax rates are determined by candidate competition. Fourth, we observe negligible deviations from labor supply behavior or voting behavior in the directions implied by altruism or inequality aversion.
    JEL: C92 D63 D72 H23
    Date: 2014–02
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:19918&r=cdm
  8. By: Asatryan, Zareh; De Witte, Kristof
    Abstract: This paper studies the role of direct democracy in ensuring efficient and cost effective provision of goods and services in the public sector. The sample consists of the population of municipalities in the German State of Bavaria, where in the mid-1990s considerable direct democratic reforms granted citizens with wide opportunities to directly participate in local affairs through binding initiatives. Using information on the municipal resources and the municipal provision of public goods, and applying a fully non-parametric approach to estimate local government overall efficiency, the analysis shows that more direct democratic activity is associated with higher government efficiency. This result suggests that more inclusive governance through direct decision-making mechanisms may induce more accountable and less inefficient governments. --
    Keywords: Direct democracy,Public sector efficiency,Conditional efficiency
    JEL: C14 D7 H7
    Date: 2014
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:zbw:zewdip:14017&r=cdm
  9. By: Jordi Brandts; David J. Cooper; Roberto A. Weber
    Abstract: We study the effectiveness of leaders for inducing coordinated organizational change to a more efficient equilibrium, i.e., a turnaround. We compare communication from leaders to incentive increases and also compare the effectiveness of randomly selected and elected leaders. While all interventions yield shifts to more efficient equilibria, communication from leaders has a greater effect than incentives. Moreover, leaders who are elected by followers are significantly better at improving their group's outcome than randomly selected ones. The improved effectiveness of elected leaders results from sending more performance-relevant messages. Our results are evidence that the way in which leaders are selected affects their legitimacy and the degree to which they influence followers. Finally, we observed that a combination of factors- incentive increases and elected leaders-yield near universal turnarounds to full efficiency.
    Keywords: Leadership, Job Selection, Coordination Failure,Experiments, Communication
    JEL: C72 C92 D83
    Date: 2014–03–10
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:aub:autbar:947.14&r=cdm
  10. By: Dotti, Valerio
    Abstract: Abstract Traditional Political Economy models typically imply a strong relationship between income inequality and public intervention in redistributive policies. Empirical evidence suggests that this may hold true only for certain kinds of policies, for instance cash transfers or education, but in the case of other policies with redistributive effects such as social security and some publicly provided private goods this may not hold true. Abstract In this paper I develop a method to derive the sign of the relationship between income inequality and degree of public intervention in education in a Probabilistic Voting model in which the consumers-voters are also allowed to choose other forms of redistribution. Abstract I show that the relationship between income inequality and governmental intervention implied in the traditional literature is mainly a result of the restrictive assumptions of those models. Abstract I also show that this method can deliver sharp predictions even in presence of those non-convexities in individual preferences that are usually described as a feature induced by public provision of education in the traditional literature in Public Economics. Abstract I argue that the relationship between income inequality and public intervention in schooling is a natural and promising field in which the tool proposed can be useful for empirical purposes and that can help to better explain some patterns described in the literature about public intervention in education.
    Keywords: Keywords: Political Economy; Probabilistic models; public provision; income inequality
    JEL: H44 H52
    Date: 2014–02–27
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:54026&r=cdm
  11. By: Etienne Farvaque (Université du Havre, Faculté des A¤aires Internationales); Alexander Mihailov (Department of Economics, University of Reading)
    Abstract: We develop a stochastic overlapping-generations model with endogenously evolving heterogeneous beliefs on the degree of inflation protection to be provided by markets versus the monetary authority. It incorporates adaptive learning from inflation history and imperfect empathy in the cultural transmission of beliefs. Analytical results on endogenous inflation beliefs and socially-optimal inflation are derived first in a within-generation voting equilibrium that defines a particular degree of inflation aversion of a society's monetary institution. Then further theoretical and simulation analysis of the intergenerational dynamics of inflation and inflation beliefs provides insights into the long-run evolution of population types and social institutions, exploring the interactions of three central forces: the persistence of inflation, the degree of inflation aversion of the central bank and the recurrent irregular cycles of agent type proportions and subsequent majority switches. Our main contribution consists in showing how the endogenous transmission of inflation beliefs and monetary institutions in a stochastic economic environment can be understood as a process of intergenerational learning from history combined with a political economy mechanism that amends legislation and a socialization process that transmits experienced knowledge.
    Keywords: evolving beliefs, in?ation aversion, adaptive learning, voting equilibrium, cultural transmission, monetary institutions
    JEL: D72 D83 E31 E58 H41 J10
    Date: 2014–03–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:rdg:emxxdp:em-dp2014-02&r=cdm
  12. By: Milla Sanes; John Schmitt
    Abstract: While the unionization of most private-sector workers is governed by the National Labor Relations Act (NLRA), the legal scope of collective bargaining for state and local public-sector workers is the domain of states and, where states allow it, local authorities. This hodge-podge of state-and-local legal frameworks is complicated enough, but recent efforts in Wisconsin, Michigan, Ohio, and other states have left the legal rights of public-sector workers even less transparent. In this report, we review the legal rights and limitations on public-sector bargaining in the 50 states and the District of Columbia, as of January 2014. Given the legal complexities, we focus on three sets of workers who make up almost half of all unionized public-sector workers: teachers, police, and firefighters, with some observations, where possible, on other state-and-local workers. For each group of workers, we examine whether public-sector workers have the right to bargain collectively; whether that right includes the ability to bargain over wages; and whether public-sector workers have the right to strike.
    Keywords: labor, employment, jobs, unions, collective bargaining, state laws, public-sector workers, teachers, fire fighters, police officers
    JEL: J J5 J50 J58 J15
    Date: 2014–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:epo:papers:2014-05&r=cdm
  13. By: Penélope Hernández (ERI-CES); Guillem Martínez-Canovas (ERI-CES); Manuel Muñoz-Herrera (University of Groningen); Lea Ellwardt (University of Groningen)
    Abstract: We examine the interplay between a person's individual preference and the social influence others exert. We provide a model of network relationships with conflicting preferences, where individuals are better off coordinating with those around them, but not all prefer the same action. We test our model in an experiment, varying the level of conflicting preferences between individuals. Our findings suggest that preferences are more salient than social influence, under conflicting preferences: subjects relate mainly with others who prefer the same. This leads to two undesirable outcomes: network segregation and social inefficiency. The same force that helps people individually hurts society.
    Keywords: Heterogeneity, Social Networks, Formation, Equilibrium selection
    JEL: C62 C72 D82 D85
    Date: 2014–01
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:dbe:wpaper:0114&r=cdm
  14. By: J.W. Fedderke and M. Mentoruzzo
    Abstract: This paper examines whether the voting behavior of Supreme Court justices in 49 cases related to securities legislation since 1936, shows systematic variation in a range of measures of the personal ideological stance of the justices, a range of measures of prevailing economic conditions, and a range of measures of prevailing political conditions. We find that the voting behavior does vary significantly with respect to all three. Conservative justices are more likely to vote against shareholder rights, and in favour of business rights, than are more liberal justices. Under increasing inflation, increased real growth, a rising public debt/GDP ratio, and a weak stock market Supreme Court justices are more likely to favour business rights than shareholder rights. Finally, across a range of measures of contestation of the political space in Congress, we find a systematic statistically significant association with the voting behavior of Supreme Court justices.
    Keywords: Supreme Court, Justice, United States
    Date: 2014
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:rza:wpaper:424&r=cdm
  15. By: JORGE HARGRAVE GONÇALVES DA SILVA
    Date: 2014
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:anp:en2012:041&r=cdm
  16. By: Michela Cella; Giovanna Iannantuoni; Elena Manzoni
    Abstract: This paper compares the ability to select the efficient policy of a parliamentary and a presidential constitutional setup. In order to do it we build a dynamic theoretical model with asymmetric information that succeeds in addressing both the politicians �accountability and the competence dimensions. The main difference between the two institutional frameworks is the presence of the confidence vote in the parliamentary system that may cause elections before the natural end of the legislature. The equilibrium predictions suggest that, exactly because of the different incentives created by the confidence vote, the parliamentary system has a higher probability of selecting the efficient policy the higher is the quality of politicians that are member of the legislative body.
    Keywords: presidential system, parliamentary system, comparison con�dence vote, hierarchical accountability
    JEL: C72 D72
    Date: 2014–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:mib:wpaper:270&r=cdm
  17. By: Binswanger, J.; Oechslin, M. (Tilburg University, Center for Economic Research)
    Abstract: Abstract: When it comes to economic reforms in developing countries, many economists agree on broad objectives (such as fostering outward orientation). Broad objectives, however, can be pursued in many di¤erent ways, and policy experimentation is often indispensable for learning which alternative works locally. We propose a simple model to study this societal learning process. The model explores the role of disagreeing beliefs about what works. It suggests that this type of disagreement can stall the societal learning process and cause economic stagnation. Interestingly, this can happen even if everybody knows that Pareto-improving reforms do exist. Our analysis is motivated by the empirical observation of a negative relationship between disagreement and economic growth among poorer countries.
    Keywords: Disagreement;experimentation;societal learning;development policy;gridlock
    JEL: D72 D78 D83 O11
    Date: 2014
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:dgr:kubcen:2014020&r=cdm

This issue is ©2014 by Stan C. Weeber. It is provided as is without any express or implied warranty. It may be freely redistributed in whole or in part for any purpose. If distributed in part, please include this notice.
General information on the NEP project can be found at https://nep.repec.org. For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese at <director@nep.repec.org>. Put “NEP” in the subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.