|
on Collective Decision-Making |
Issue of 2012‒10‒27
eight papers chosen by |
By: | Kelly Rowe; Ignacio Lago; Santiago Lago Peñas |
Abstract: | Why does the leftist party vote increase when turnout increases in some countries and not in others? Why does this happen in some instances in time but not in others? Thus far there exists no academic consensus on the relationship between turnout and electoral results. This paper argues that in order to adequately address these questions we need to focus on three elements: class voting, the mechanisms behind whether the correlation is observed over the short or longterm, and the use of more rigorous model specifications. By looking at the cases of Spain and Portugal, we find a correlation in the short and long-term for Spain but not for Portugal and this is due namely to the prominence of class voting in the former. |
Keywords: | Voting behoviour, elections, turnout |
JEL: | D72 |
Date: | 2012–09 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:vig:wpaper:1201&r=cdm |
By: | Wojciech Charemza; Daniel Ladley |
Abstract: | This paper considers the effectiveness of monetary policy committee voting when the inflation forecast signals, upon which decisions are based, may be subject to manipulation. Using a discrete time intertemporal model, we examine the distortions resulting from such manipulation under a three-way voting system, similar to that used by the Bank of Sweden. We find that voting itself creates persistence in inflation. Whilst altering the forecast signal, even if well intentioned, results in a diminished probability of achieving the inflation target. However, if committee members ‘learn’ in a Bayesian manner, this problem is mitigated. |
Keywords: | Voting Rules; Monetary Policy; Inflation Targeting |
JEL: | E47 E52 E58 |
Date: | 2012–10 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:lec:leecon:12/23&r=cdm |
By: | Robert Brooks (Department of Econometrics and Business Statistics, Monash University, Melbourne, Australia); Mark N. Harris (Department of Econometrics and Quantitative Modelling, School of Economics and Finance, Curtin Business School, Curtin University, Perth, Australia, WA 6845); Christopher Spencer (School of Business and Economics, Loughborough University, UK) |
Abstract: | We extend Harris and Zhao (2007) by proposing a (Panel) Inflated Ordered Probit model, and demonstrate its usefulness by applying it to Bank of England Monetary Policy Committee voting data. |
Keywords: | Panel Inflated Ordered Probit, random effects, inflated outcomes, voting, Monetary Policy Committee |
JEL: | E5 C3 |
Date: | 2012–10 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:lbo:lbowps:2012_09&r=cdm |
By: | Sinha, Pankaj; Thomas, Ashley Rose; Ranjan, Varun |
Abstract: | Contemporary discussions on 2012 U.S Presidential election mention that economic variables such as unemployment rate, inflation, budget deficit/surplus, public debt, tax policy and healthcare spending will be deciding elements in the forthcoming November election. Certain researchers like Bartells and Zaller (2001), Lewis-Beck and Rice (1982), and Lichtman and Keilis-Borok (1996) have investigated the significance of non-economic variables in forecasting the U.S election. This paper investigates the influence of combination of various economic and non-economic variables as factors influencing the outcome of 2012 U.S Presidential election, using statistical factor analysis. The obtained factor scores are used to predict the vote share of the incumbent using regression model. The paper also employs logit and probit models to predict the probability of win for the incumbent candidate in 2012 U.S Presidential election. It is found that the factors combining above economic variables are insignificant in deciding the outcome of the 2012 election. The factor combining the non-economic variables such as Gallup Ratings, GIndex, wars and scandals has been found significantly influencing the public perception of the performance of the Government and its policies, which in turn affects the voting decision. The proposed factor regression model forecasts that the Democrat candidate Mr. Barack Obama is likely to get a vote share between 51.84% - 54.26% with 95% confidence interval in the forthcoming November 2012 U.S Presidential election. While, the proposed logit and probit models forecast the probability of win for the Democrat candidate Mr. Barack Obama to be 67.37% and 67.00%, respectively. |
Keywords: | Factor Analysis; Logit and Probit model; 2012 U.S Presidential Election; Economic and non-economic variables |
JEL: | C53 C5 D72 C2 C01 C1 |
Date: | 2012–10–15 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:42062&r=cdm |
By: | Oguro, Kazumasa; Ishida, Ryo |
Abstract: | This paper constructs an overlapping generations model in order to demonstrate low political intervention and interaction in the working and retired generations affect the allocation rate in future growth-stimulating public investment and the public pension. It also analyzes the possibility of moving to a voting system that allocates parliamentary seats according to life expectancy. The presented results suggest the following three main findings. Firstly, the voting system is important when population demographics change. Declining birthrates and an aging population may shorten the temporal perspective for policymaking over time. Any theoretical transition from the current voting system to a voting system that allocates parliamentary seats according to life expectancy would thus lengthen the temporal perspective for policymaking, potentially increasing the public investment rate and improving the utilities of the working and future generations. Secondly, when age-based voting turnout disparity is high, the shift from the current voting system to one based on life expectancy and region or life expectancy and age is possible. Thirdly, if both transitions from the current system are possible, moving to the latter would offer greater possibility for increasing the utilities of the working generation and future generations than moving to the former. |
Keywords: | Public investment, Public pension, OLG model, Generational-based constituency bloc, Demeny voting system, Life expectancy |
JEL: | D90 H50 H60 J18 O20 |
Date: | 2012–10 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:hit:cisdps:571&r=cdm |
By: | Marina Azzimonti (FRB of Philadelphia) |
Abstract: | This paper studies the effects of asymmetries in re-election probabilities across parties on public policy and its subsequent propagation to the economy. The struggle between groups that disagree on targeted transfers results in governments being endogenously short-sighted: Systematic underinvestment in infrastructure and overspending on public goods arise, beyond what is observed in symmetric environments. Because the party enjoying an electoral advantage is less short-sighted, it devotes a larger proportion of revenues to productive investment. Hence, political turnover induces economic fluctuations in an otherwise deterministic environment. I characterize analytically the long-run distribution of allocations, and show that output increases with electoral advantage, despite the fact that governments expand. Volatility is non-monotonic in electoral advantage and is an additional source of inefficiency. Using panel data from US States I confirm these findings, and show that there is an inverted U-shape relation between the volatility of public policy and electoral advantage. |
Date: | 2012 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:red:sed012:91&r=cdm |
By: | Leeat Yariv (California Institute of Technology); Alessandro Lizzeri (New York University); Alberto Bisin (New York University) |
Abstract: | Behavioral economics presents a "paternalistic" rationale for government intervention. Current literature focuses on benevolent government. This paper introduces politicians who may indulge/exploit these behavioral biases. We present an analysis of the novel features that arise when the political process is populated by voters who may be time inconsistent, a' la Phelps and Polak (1968) and Laibson (1997). Time inconsistent voters exhibit demand for commitment. We show that electorally accountable politicians may choose policies that interfere with individuals' desire to commit, and that government may not be very effective in satisfying the demand for commitment. |
Date: | 2012 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:red:sed012:92&r=cdm |
By: | Cubel, Maria (University of Barcelona) |
Abstract: | In this paper we analyze the political viability of equalization rules in the context of a decentralized country. We explore the idea that when equalization rules are perceived as unfair, regions may initiate a political conflict. Regions are formed by identical individuals who, through lobbying, try to obtain a higher share from the (equalization) pool of resources. Political conflict is measured as the total contribution to lobbying. We conclude that the onset of conflict depends on the degree of publicness of the regional budget and the relative size of the regions. When regional budgets are used to provide pure public goods, full fiscal equalization is politically feasible. However, fiscal equalization is not immune to conflict when budgets are used to provide private goods or a linear combination of private and public goods. The likelihood of political conflict decreases as the regions become similar in size. |
Keywords: | political conflict; lobbying; fiscal equalization; social decision rules |
JEL: | D31 D74 H77 R51 |
Date: | 2012–10–19 |
URL: | http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ris:nepswp:2012_009&r=cdm |