New Economics Papers
on Collective Decision-Making
Issue of 2006‒12‒04
twelve papers chosen by



  1. Mahatma Gandhi and the Prisoner’s Dilemma: Strategic Civil Disobedience and Great Britain’s Great Loss of Empire in India By Siddiky, Chowdhury Irad Ahmed
  2. How Elitism Undermines the Study of Voter Competence By Lupia, Arthur
  3. Were Bush Tax Cut Supporters "Simply Ignorant?" A Second Look at Conservatives and Liberals in "Homer Gets a Tax Cut" By Lupia, Arthur; Levine, Adam S.; Menning, Jesse O.; Sin, Gisela
  4. When Can Politicians Scare Citizens Into Supporting Bad Policies? A Theory of Incentives with Fear-Based Content By Lupia, Arthur; Menning, Jesse
  5. POLITICAL PRICE CYCLES IN REGULATED INDUSTRIES: THEORY AND EVIDENCE By Rodrigo Menon S. Moita; Claudio Paiva
  6. The social norm of leaving the toilet seat down: A game theoretic analysis By Siddiqi, Hammad
  7. Public Ignorance and Estate Tax Repeal: The Effect of Partisan Differences and Survey Incentives By Krupnikov, Yanna; Levine, Adam S.; Lupia, Arthur; Prior, Markus
  8. Declared vs. revealed yardstick competition: local government efficiency in Norway By Tovmo Per; Revelli Federico
  9. Iraq: Private ownership of oil and the quest for democracy By Razzak, Weshah
  10. What Citizens Know Depends on How You Ask Them: Political Knowledge and Political Learning Skills By Lupia, Arthur; Prior, Markus
  11. Committees Versus Individuals: An Experimental Analysis of Monetary Policy Decision Making By Lombardelli, Clare; Proudman, James; Talbot, James
  12. The Economics of Young Democracies: Policies and Performance By Kapstein, Ethan; Converse, Nathan

  1. By: Siddiky, Chowdhury Irad Ahmed
    Abstract: This paper examines the relationship between statutory monopoly and collective action as a multi-person assurance game culminating in an end to British Empire in India. In a simple theoretical model, it is demonstrated whether or not a collective good enjoys (or is perceived to enjoy) pure jointness of production and why the evolutionary stable strategy of non-violence was supposed to work on the principle that the coordinated reaction of a ethnically differentiated religious crowd to a conflict between two parties (of colonizer and colonized) over confiscatory salt taxation would significantly affect its course. Following Mancur Olson (1965) and Dennis Chong (1991), a model of strategic civil disobedience is created which is used to demonstrate how collective action can be used to produce an all-or-nothing public good to achieve economic and political independence.
    Keywords: confiscatory taxation; multi-person assurance game; strategic civil disobedience
    JEL: N45
    Date: 2005–05–02
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:147&r=cdm
  2. By: Lupia, Arthur
    Abstract: A form of elitism undermines much writing on voter competence. The elitist move occurs when an author uses a self-serving worldview as the basis for evaluating voters. Such elitism is apparent in widely cited measures of “political knowledge” and in common claims about what voters should know. The elitist move typically limits the credibility and practical relevance of the analysis by leading writers to draw unreliable conclusions about voter competence. I propose a more constructive way of thinking about what voters know. Its chief virtue is its consistency with basic facts about the relationship between information and choice.
    Keywords: information; search; competence; political knowledge; public policy
    JEL: H00 D8
    Date: 2006
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:349&r=cdm
  3. By: Lupia, Arthur; Levine, Adam S.; Menning, Jesse O.; Sin, Gisela
    Abstract: In a recent edition of Perspectives on Politics, Larry Bartels examines the high levels of support for tax cuts signed into law by President Bush in 2001. In so doing, he characterizes the opinions of “ordinary people” as lacking “a moral basis” and as being based on “simple-minded and sometimes misguided considerations of self interest.” He concludes that “the strong plurality support for Bush’s tax cut...is entirely attributable to simple ignorance.” Our analysis of the same data reveals different results. We show that for a large and politically relevant class of respondents – people who describe themselves as “conservative” or “Republican” – rising information levels increase support for the tax cuts. Indeed, using Bartels’ measure of political information, we show that the Republican respondents rated “most informed” supported the tax cuts at extraordinarily high levels (over 96%). For these citizens, Bartels’ claim that “better-informed respondents were much more likely to express negative views about the 2001 tax cut” is simply untrue. We then show that Bartels’ results depend on a very strong assumption about how information affects public opinion. He restricts all respondents -- whether liberal or conservative, Republican or Democrat – to respond to increasing information levels in identical ways. In other words, he assumes that if more information about the tax cut makes liberals less likely to support it, then conservatives must follow suit. This assumption is very presumptive about the policy trade-offs that different people should make. Our analysis, by contrast, allows people of different partisan or ideological identities to react to higher information levels in varying ways. This flexibility has many benefits, one of which is a direct test of Bartels’ restrictive assumption. We demonstrate that the assumption is untrue. Examined several ways, our findings suggest that much of the support for the tax cut was attributable to something other than “simple ignorance.” Bartels’ approach is based on a very strong presumption about how citizens should think and what they should think about. We advocate a different approach, one that takes questions of public policy seriously while respecting ideological and partisan differences in opinion and interest. Indeed, citizens have reasons for the opinions and interests they have. We may or may not agree with them. However, we, as social scientists, can contribute more by offering reliable explanations of these reasons than we can by judging them prematurely. By turning our attention to explaining differences of opinion, we can help to forge a stronger and more credible foundation for progress in meeting critical social needs.
    Keywords: tax cut; President Bush; Republicans; conservatives; information; competence; public policy
    JEL: D80 H23 D8
    Date: 2005
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:348&r=cdm
  4. By: Lupia, Arthur; Menning, Jesse
    Abstract: Analysts make competing claims about when and how politicians can use fear to gain support for suboptimal policies. Using a model, we clarify how common attributes of fear affect politicians’ abilities to achieve self-serving outcomes that are bad for voters. In it, a politician provides information about a threat. His statement need not be true. How citizens respond differs from most game-theoretic models – we proceed from more dynamic (and realistic) assumptions about how citizens think. Our conclusions counter popular claims about how easily politicians use fear to manipulate citizens, yield different policy advice than does recent scholarship on counterterrorism, and highlight issues (abstract, distant) and leaders (secretive) for which recent findings by political psychologists and public opinion scholars will – and will not – generalize.
    Keywords: emotions; behavioral economics; game theory; political science; incentives
    JEL: D83 H30 C72
    Date: 2005
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:102&r=cdm
  5. By: Rodrigo Menon S. Moita; Claudio Paiva
    Date: 2006
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:anp:en2006:126&r=cdm
  6. By: Siddiqi, Hammad
    Abstract: We model the toilet seat problem as a 2 player non-cooperative game. We find that the social norm of leaving the toilet seat down is inefficient. However, to the dismay of “mankind”, we also find that the social norm of leaving the seat down after use is a trembling-hand perfect equilibrium. Hence, sadly, this norm is not likely to go away.
    Keywords: Trembling-hand perfection; social norm
    JEL: C7
    Date: 2006–11–16
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:856&r=cdm
  7. By: Krupnikov, Yanna; Levine, Adam S.; Lupia, Arthur; Prior, Markus
    Abstract: We re-examine whether the broad support for repeal of the estate tax is a result of citizen ignorance. We find that increasing information about the estate tax or politics in general has very different effects on Republicans and Democrats. While high and low-information Republicans support estate tax repeal, Democratic support is higher among those who know less. However, most highly-informed people in both parties support repeal. We also show that standard surveys overestimate the extent of misinformation about the estate tax. Therefore, “ignorance” is not a compelling explanation of why so many people support estate tax repeal.
    Keywords: estate tax; voter competence; survey research; experimental economics; public policy
    JEL: H20 H30 K10
    Date: 2006
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:346&r=cdm
  8. By: Tovmo Per; Revelli Federico (University of Turin)
    Abstract: This paper investigates whether the production efficiency of Norwegian local governments exhibits a spatial pattern that is compatible with the hy­pothesis of yardstick competition. In order to check whether yardstick com­petition is really responsible far the observed spatial pattern, and to rule out alternative theoretical explanations, the paper exploits unique information from a survey on Norwegian local governments, where local public officials are explicitly asked whether they compare their own performances in the provision of public services to those of other governments (benchmarking). Merging the latter information - "declared" yardstick competition - with the observed interdependence in local efficiency measures - "revealed" yardstick competition - the paper provides evidence that comparative performance evaluation generates spatial auto-correlation in local efficiency indicators.
    Date: 2006–05
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:uto:dipeco:200605&r=cdm
  9. By: Razzak, Weshah
    Abstract: I argue that state-ownership and state-management of oil on behalf of the Iraqi people is not conducive to democracy and inconsistent with the principles of free market. I also argue that it can adversely affect economic development and might further impoverish the average Iraqi citizen. To resolve the problems, this note proposes a change to the “political” rules; i.e., change the Iraqi constitution, and provides an economic strategy to transfer oil wealth to the Iraqi people.
    Keywords: Oil; private ownership; development
    JEL: Q43 Q32 P14 Q48
    Date: 2006
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:54&r=cdm
  10. By: Lupia, Arthur; Prior, Markus
    Abstract: Surveys provide widely-cited measures of political knowledge. Do unusual aspects of survey interviews reduce their relevance? To address this question, we embedded a set of experiments in a representative survey of over 1200 Americans. A control group answered political knowledge questions in a typical survey context. Respondents in treatment groups received the same questions in different contexts. One group received a monetary incentive for answering questions correctly. Others were given more time to answer the questions. The treatments increase the number of correct answers by 11-24 percent. Our findings imply that conventional knowledge measures confound respondents’ recall of political information and their motivation to engage the survey question. The measures also provide unreliable assessments of respondents’ abilities to access information that they have stored in places other than their immediately available memories. As a result, existing knowledge measures likely underestimate peoples’ capacities for informed decision making.
    Keywords: political knowledge; economic knowledge; experimental economics; incentives; survey
    JEL: H30 H31 C90
    Date: 2005
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:103&r=cdm
  11. By: Lombardelli, Clare; Proudman, James; Talbot, James
    Abstract: We report the results of an experimental analysis of monetary policy decision making under uncertainty. A large sample of economics students played a simple monetary policy game, both as individuals and in committees of five players. Our findings - that groups make better decisions than individuals - accord with previous work by Blinder and Morgan. We also attempt to establish why this is so. Some of the improvement is related to the ability of committees to strip out the effect of bad play, but there is a significant additional improvement, which we associate with players learning from each other’s interest rate decisions.
    Keywords: Monetary policy; experimental economics; central banking; uncertainty
    JEL: G00 G0
    Date: 2005–02–08
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:823&r=cdm
  12. By: Kapstein, Ethan; Converse, Nathan
    Abstract: Since the “third wave” of democratization began in 1974, nearly 100 states have adopted democratic forms of government, including, of course, most of the former Soviet bloc nations. Policy-makers in the west have expressed the hope that this democratic wave will extend even further, to the Middle East and onward to China. But the durability of this new democratic age remains an open question. By some accounts, at least half of the world’s young democracies—often referred to in the academic literature as being “unconsolidated” or “fragile”—are still struggling to develop their political institutions, and several have reverted back to authoritarian rule. Among the countries in the early stages of democratic institution building are states vital to U.S. national security interests, including Afghanistan and Iraq. The ability of fledgling democracies to maintain popular support depends in part on the ability of their governments to deliver economic policies that meet with widespread approval. But what sorts of economic policies are these, and are they necessarily the same as the policies required for tackling difficult issues of economic stabilization and reform? Conversely, what sorts of economic policies are most likely to spark a backlash against young and fragile democratic regimes? Do the leaders of young democracies face trade-offs as they ponder their electoral and economic strategies? These are among the questions we explore in this paper, which provides an overview of the monograph we are currently writing on the economics of young democracies. We do so first by exploring the hypothesized relationships between democratic politics and economic policy, as well as the findings of several important empirical studies with respect to the economic performance of young democracies around the world. We then provide some descriptive statistics on how the new democracies have fared in practice, making use of a new dataset that we have compiled (and which, among other things, is more up-to-date than most others cited herein). Do the data reveal any distinctive economic patterns with respect to democratic consolidation and reversal? We will show that they do. In particular, we find that deteriorating or stagnant economic performance constitutes a red flag or warning signal that the country is at risk of democratic reversal. Moreover, we find considerable variation in economic performance, suggesting that the design of political institutions in new democracies may have a significant influence on the probability of their survival.
    Keywords: democracy; economic growth; inflation; political development
    JEL: P16 P17 E52 E62
    Date: 2006–03
    URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:553&r=cdm

General information on the NEP project can be found at https://nep.repec.org. For comments please write to the director of NEP, Marco Novarese at <director@nep.repec.org>. Put “NEP” in the subject, otherwise your mail may be rejected.
NEP’s infrastructure is sponsored by the School of Economics and Finance of Massey University in New Zealand.